You are on page 1of 24

No.

653 November 18, 2009

The Myth of the Compact City


Why Compact Development Is Not the Way to
Reduce Carbon Dioxide Emissions
by Randal O’Toole

Executive Summary

Proponents of compact development argue sent a huge intrusion on private property rights,
that rebuilding American urban areas to higher personal freedom, and mobility. They are also
densities is vital for reducing greenhouse gas emis- fraught with risks. Urban planners and econo-
sions. Compact city policies call for reducing dri- mists are far from unanimous about whether
ving by housing a higher percentage of people in such policies will reduce greenhouse gas emis-
multi-family and mixed-use developments, reduc- sions. Some even raise the possibility that com-
ing the average lot sizes of single-family homes, pact city policies could increase emissions by
redesigning streets and neighborhoods to be more increasing roadway congestion.
pedestrian friendly, concentrating jobs in selected Such reductions are insignificant compared
areas, and spending more on mass transit and less with the huge costs that compact development
on highways. would impose on the nation. These costs include
The Obama administration has endorsed these reduced worker productivity, less affordable hous-
policies. Secretary of Transportation Ray LaHood ing, increased traffic congestion, higher taxes or
and Secretary of Housing and Urban Development reduced urban services, and higher consumer costs.
Shaun Donovan have agreed to require metropoli- Those who believe we must reduce carbon emis-
tan areas to adopt compact-development policies sions should reject compact development as expen-
or risk losing federal transportation and housing sive, risky, and distracting from tools, such as car-
funds. LaHood has admitted that the goal of this bon taxes, that can have greater, more immediate,
program is to “coerce people out of their cars.” and more easily monitored effects on greenhouse
As such, compact-development policies repre- gas emissions.

Randal O’Toole is a senior fellow with the Cato Institute and author of Gridlock: Why We Are Stuck in Traffic
and What to Do about It (forthcoming).
Compact tions”—could reduce 2050 greenhouse gas
development Introduction emissions by 9 to 15 percent.4
Another 2009 report from the Center for
policies, admits The Obama administration has endorsed Clean Air Policy promoted “greenhouse gas
Transportation proposals to direct metropolitan areas to reductions through smart growth and im-
become more “compact” in order to reduce proved transportation choices” and proposed
Secretary Ray greenhouse gas emissions. Such a compact- that cap-and-trade revenues be invested in
LaHood, are development policy calls for increasing urban such programs. The report went further and
designed “to population densities, housing more people in argued that such changes would be “cost-
multi-family and mixed-use developments, effective” and even “profitable.”5
coerce people out investing more in mass transit and less in Most recently, a report from the Transpor-
of their cars.” infrastructure for personal transportation, tation Research Board, Driving and the Built
and concentrating jobs in selected areas. Environment, concluded that doubling the
The major premises behind this policy are density of most new development and making
that people living in compact cities drive less, other land-use changes such as concentrating
and that the United States cannot meet targets jobs, mixed-use developments, and significant
for reducing greenhouse gas emissions with- transit improvements, could reduce miles of
out reducing the growth of driving. The “trans- driving and auto-related carbon dioxide emis-
portation sector cannot do its fair share to sions by up to 11 percent.6
meet this [greenhouse gas reduction] target Coming at a time when Congress is debat-
through vehicle and fuel technology alone,” ing both climate policy and transportation
says Growing Cooler, a 2008 report from the reauthorization, these reports are clearly
Urban Land Institute. This is because, the aimed at promoting a national smart-growth
report explains, the predicted growth in dri- policy that would dictate land uses and trans-
ving is greater than predicted reductions in portation spending for the next several dec-
emissions from more efficient cars and alter- ades. The reports have clearly influenced the
native fuels.1 Obama administration, which has endorsed
To reduce driving, Growing Cooler advocat- the goal of reducing driving through compact-
ed the use of “compact development” com- city policies. The secretaries of transportation
bined with “expanded transportation alterna- and housing and urban development have
tives.” Compact development, says Growing signed an agreement to require metropolitan
Cooler, means “higher average ‘blended’ densi- areas to adopt compact development policies.7
ties” along with “a mix of land uses, develop- Secretary of Transportation Ray LaHood has
ment of strong population and employment admitted that these policies are designed to
centers, interconnection of streets, and the “coerce people out of their cars.”8
design of structures and spaces at a human Yet the reports supporting compact cities
scale.”2 contain major flaws. First, they typically over-
One month after publication of Growing state the effects of compact development on
Cooler, the Brookings Institute released Shrink- greenhouse gas emissions. Second, they
ing the Carbon Footprint of Metropolitan America. ignore or vastly underestimate the costs of
The report urged the federal government to compact development, alternative forms of
use its housing and transportation programs transportation, and restrictions on personal
to encourage or require metropolitan areas “to mobility. Further, they ignore or underesti-
expand transit and compact development.”3 mate the risks that compact development
In 2009, the Urban Land Institute and sev- will not produce the intended effects or that
eral other groups published Moving Cooler, a unintended consequences will prove far more
sequel to Growing Cooler. The report claimed costly than any benefits that result.
that “smart growth”—a combination of com- The reports’ failure to accurately assess
pact development and “improved travel op- benefits and costs obscures the fact that com-

2
pact city policies are extremely expensive, yet evil consequences of which are ever with us.”10
they will likely yield negligible (and possibly In 1947, the British Parliament passed the
negative) environmental benefits. Given limit- Town and Country Planning Act, which
ed resources, if other means of reducing green- could be described as the first modern com-
house gases are more cost efficient, then pro- pact-city law. This law set aside vast regions
moting or requiring compact development of rural land as greenbelts and mandated the
will make it more difficult to achieve emission construction of high-density, high-rise hous-
reduction targets. ing within existing cities along Radiant City
lines.
Unlike the United States, which built pub-
History of Compact lic housing only for the poor, the British gov-
City Planning ernment built these apartments for working-
class and middle-class families. Many of the
For more than 75 years, architects and buildings proved to be so unlivable, observes
urban planners have proposed compact devel- Hall, that “the remarkable fact was how long
opment as an alternative to low-density sub- it took for anyone to see that it was wrong.”11
urbs, which they derisively term “sprawl.” In By the late 1960s, few people were willing to
addition to higher-density housing, most live in such apartments even at heavily subsi-
Compact
compact city proposals also include plans to dized rents, and so by 1970, says Hall, “the development
make neighborhoods more pedestrian-friend- great Corbusian rebuild was over.”12 proposals date
ly and include investments in mass transit The United States built its Radiant City
and other alternatives to auto driving. To- housing exclusively for low-income families, back at least to
gether, compact development and alternative but had the same experience. The housing the 1930s, and
transportation projects are sometimes called projects became so plagued by crime and van-
“smart growth.” dalism that most have been demolished.13
the British
Although the term smart growth was not One of the leading critics of the standard Parliament
applied to these policies until 1996, the desire urban renewal practices of the 1950s—clearing passed the first
on the part of urban planners and some envi- “slums” and replacing them with high-rise
ronmentalists for higher urban densities long housing—was Jane Jacobs, author of The Death compact-
predates that year or any concerns about glob- and Life of Great American Cities. Jacobs lived in a development
al climate change. Criticism of low-density mid-rise, mixed-use, inner-city neighborhood law in 1947.
suburbs dates back at least to the 1930s.9 First that was slated for urban renewal, and she
in Europe and later in the United States, those sought to prove that her neighborhood was
critics have sought to use the power of govern- “lively,” and not a blighted slum that needed
ment to herd large segments of the population to be replaced.14
into high-density cities and to prevent owners Urban planners learned a lesson from The
of rural land from developing their property Death and Life, but it was the wrong one. Instead
for residential uses. of realizing that cities are too complicated to be
One of the first to promote such policies centrally planned, they concluded that central
was Le Corbusier, a Swiss-French architect planners should promote Jacobs’s mid-rise
who promoted the reconstruction of cities neighborhoods instead of Corbusier’s high-
into vast regions of high-rise apartments that rise apartments.
he called “Radiant Cities.” His ideas so heavi- This transition is apparent in a 1973
ly influenced urban planners throughout the book, Compact City. “The problems of urban
world in the 1940s and 1950s that planning development,” write authors George Dantzig
historian Peter Hall calls Corbusier “the Ra- and Thomas Saaty, “are too crucial to the
sputin of this tale,” both because Radiant Cit- future to be left to real-estate developers”—in
ies turned out to be unlivable and because of other words, private landowners who meet
his authoritarian approach to planning, “the market demand by building low-density sub-

3
urbs. Central planners should insist on high-
er-density development.15 The Solution in Search
The book’s main proposals were “in some of a Problem
respects based on Radiant City lines” (which
reveals how slow planners are to learn from Throughout most of this history, com-
their mistakes). As an alternative, however, pact development was a solution in search of
the authors’ proposed that density could be a problem. Early advocates claimed that
achieved using Jacobs’s “lively neighbor- denser development was needed to preserve
hoods.”16 Either way, the authors call for a farmlands. Yet the United States has a billion
top-down planning approach that would acres of agricultural lands, less than 40 per-
give property owners and homebuyers little cent of which are actually used for growing
choice but to accept the dictates of the sup- crops, while the nation’s urban areas occupy
posedly omniscient planners. only about 100 million acres.21 So, compact
In the 1980s, a number of architects pro- development for the purpose of farm preser-
posed to build Jacobs’s lively neighborhoods vation made little sense.
from scratch. On the East Coast, Andres Duany In the 1970s, advocates of compact devel-
suggested that such “neotraditional” neighbor- opment argued that it would reduce air pol-
hoods would have a stronger sense of commu- lution and save energy because people living
nity than traditional low-density suburbs.17 On in compact cities would drive less. Yet it
the West Coast, Peter Calthorpe claimed that proved to be far easier to simply build clean-
pedestrian-oriented “urban villages” would be er, more fuel-efficient cars than to complete-
less “dependent” on the automobile.18 These ly rebuild American cities.
ideas soon became known as “New Urbanism.” Between 1970 and 2007, for example, urban
New Urbanists, however, soon ran into a driving increased by 250 percent, but auto-
brick wall of market reality: surveys and actu- related air pollution declined by more than
al buying habits have repeatedly shown that two-thirds.22 Meanwhile, Americans respond-
the vast majority of Americans aspire to live ed to higher gas prices in the 1970s and early
in a single-family home with a large yard.19 1980s by buying cars in the 1990s that were an
While New Urbanists accepted some single- average of 40 percent more fuel efficient than
family homes, they wanted to increase the those available in the early 1970s.23 In 1991, for
percentage of people living in multi-family example, Americans drove 41 percent more
After the housing and build single-family homes on miles than in 1978, while using only 3 percent
tiny lots. There is a small market for high- more fuel.24 After gas prices fell, Americans
developer of a density, mixed-use neighborhoods, but in bought larger cars, but technological improve-
New Urban many cities that market is easily met by exist- ments produced a continuing increase of ton-
ing older neighborhoods. miles-per-gallon.25 This shows that consider-
project designed As a result, many early New Urban devel- able progress can be made in improving fuel
by Peter Calthorpe opments were financial failures. After the first economy without reducing mobility.
went bankrupt, developer of Calthorpe’s Laguna West, near Another early argument for regulating
Sacramento, went bankrupt, a later developer sprawl was that the cost of providing infra-
Calthorpe went reconfigured and completed it as a tradition- structure to low-density communities was
into the business al suburb. Calthorpe soon went into the busi- significantly greater than in higher-density
of helping cities ness of helping cities write codes mandating areas.26 The most detailed study of this ques-
New Urban development. Such mandates tion concluded that low-density suburban
writing codes came to be known as “smart growth,” a term development imposes about $11,000 per res-
mandating that became popular partly because advocates idence more in urban-service costs on com-
often construe anyone who supports proper- munities than more compact development.27
New Urban ty rights and freedom of choice as promoting Some have questioned this number.28 But
development. “dumb growth.”20 even if valid, most homebuyers would gladly

4
add $11,000 to the cost of a $150,000 home Now compact-city advocates have hitched No one
in order to have a good-sized yard and not their wagon to the climate-change debate. complained
share a wall with next-door neighbors. However, instead of advocating the most effi-
In the 1980s and 1990s, some New Urban cient (and thus resource-conservative) ways about sprawl
advocates argued that denser neighborhoods of reducing greenhouse gas emissions, these when suburbs
had a stronger sense of community. Studies advocates have co-opted climate concerns to
have found, however, that suburbs actually justify their preferences for urban planning.
were occupied
have more social interactions than denser Consider: solely by upper
cities.29 Even the data in Robert Putnam’s and middle
Bowling Alone, which promoted the notion • The lead author of Growing Cooler, Reid
that Americans were losing their sense of Ewing, was also the lead author of the classes. It was
community, showed that suburbanites had study (which he brags is “the most wide- only when
higher social participation rates than resi- ly reported planning study ever”) that working-class
dents of dense cities.30 erroneously claimed suburbs make peo-
In the early 2000s, compact-city supporters ple obese.34 families moved to
jumped on the obesity issue by claiming that • Growing Cooler co-author Keith Bartholo- the suburbs that
suburbs make people fat. In fact, even studies mew was staff attorney for 1000 Friends of
prepared by smart-growth supporters found Oregon in 1989, where he directed the
critics proposed
that the differences in obesity rates between Land Use-Transportation-Air Quality proj- to force them
low- and high-density areas were trivial. One ect that developed much of the modern into compact
study found, for example, that about 2 percent conception of compact development.35
more people in low-density Atlanta are obese Another co-author, Don Chen, is a former developments.
than in high-density San Francisco.31 More staff member of the Surface Transpor-
careful studies have found “no evidence that tation Policy Project, which has sought to
urban sprawl causes obesity.” In fact, these reduce driving since its creation in 1990.
studies say, compact-city advocates confused • Many of the organizations behind the
cause and effect: “individuals who are more Moving Cooler report, including the Ameri-
likely to be obese choose to live in more can Public Transportation Association,
sprawling neighborhoods.”32 Environmental Defense Fund, Natural
If all these reasons for supporting compact Resources Defense Council, and Environ-
cities are wrong, then why is the idea so persis- mental Protection Agency, have promoted
tent? The answer, at least in part, says Peter compact cities for at least 15 years.
Hall, is that it is a class conflict. Ironically, Hall • Several people listed on the Center for
observes, before 1920 the main goal of urban Clean Air Policy report as having provid-
planners was to move working-class people ed “assistance” to the authors have also
from high-density inner-city tenements to promoted compact cities.
low-density suburbs. No one complained
about urban sprawl when low-density suburbs Some, though certainly not all, of the mem-
were occupied solely by the upper and middle bers of the Transportation Research Board
classes. But when working-class families start- committee that oversaw that organization’s
ed moving to the suburbs—more due to Henry report have also long been compact-city advo-
Ford’s mass-produced automobiles than to cates.
anything urban planners did—conflicts be- In other words, these reports have been
tween upper- and lower-class tastes led to a written or influenced by people who support-
backlash.33 While often giving lip service to the ed compact development long before climate
idea of mixed-income communities, the elites change became a major issue. Now they are
decided to promote policies that made single- using climate change to justify imposing their
family housing unaffordable to all but the preferred form of urban planning on major
wealthy. U.S. metropolitan areas.

5
Rebuilding American cities to more com-
pact standards would certainly qualify as a Compact Cities and
megaproject. Bent Flyvbjerg, a Danish planner Greenhouse Gases
who has studied numerous megaprojects,
observes that megaproject advocates are often All of the reports discussed in this paper
guilty of optimism bias, in which they overesti- take it for granted that the United States must
mate benefits and underestimate costs, and reduce carbon dioxide emissions by as much
strategic misrepresentation, in which they skew as 80 percent from 1990 levels—which would
data to make their project look more favorable mean 83 percent from 2007 levels. Though
than it really is.36 many climatologists dispute this goal, such
For example, Growing Cooler optimistically disputes are beyond the scope of this paper.41
estimated that building 60 percent of new Instead, the point of this paper is that if the
urban development to compact standards United States decides to reduce greenhouse gas emis-
would reduce 2030 carbon dioxide emissions sions, there are more cost-efficient policies to achieve
by 79 million tons.37 Somewhat more realisti- this goal than compact development. Given that
cally, Moving Cooler estimated that building 64 resources are limited, any project that reduces
percent of new urban development to com- greenhouse gas emissions in a non-cost-effec-
If the pact standards would reduce 2030 carbon tive manner will simply make it more difficult
United States dioxide emissions by only 22 million tons, to meet emission reduction targets.
decides to reduce indicating that Growing Cooler overestimated According to a McKinsey and Company
the effects of compact development by nearly report, the United States can meet emission
greenhouse gas four times.38 In its own example of optimism reduction targets by investing in projects that
emissions, bias, however, Moving Cooler projects that the cost less than $50 per ton of carbon-dioxide-
cost of building up to 90 percent of all new equivalent emissions. Close to half of the
other policies urban development in the U.S. to compact reductions, the company found, would actual-
are far more standards would be only $1.5 billion.39 ly have a negative cost: though they may
cost-efficient Policy advocates who couch their ideas in require up-front investments, they would save
language that disguises the weaknesses of their money in the long run by reducing energy
than compact proposals are guilty of strategic misrepresenta- costs. These projects would include designing
development. tion. For example, Growing Cooler’s repeated cars and light trucks that are lighter-weight
statement that transportation accounts for and have less wind and rolling resistance.42
one-third of greenhouse gas emissions (modi- In contrast to McKinsey’s rigorous analy-
fied to 28 percent in Moving Cooler) obscures sis of cost-effectiveness, none of the reports
the fact that urban driving of personal vehi- advocating compact development show that
cles—the form of transportation advocates such policies would be cost-effective, and
seek to reduce through compact develop- most do not even mention cost-effectiveness.
ment—accounts for less than 13 percent of In fact, to the extent that compact develop-
emissions, while the other 20 percent comes ment can reduce greenhouse gas emissions at
from freight, mass transportation, and interci- all, it would do so only at a cost far greater
ty travel.40 than $50 per ton. This means it should be
A careful reading of the various compact- among the last policies to be adopted in
city reports reveal numerous other optimism response to climate concerns.
biases and strategic misrepresentations that
overestimate the benefits and underestimate Growing Cooler
the costs of these proposals. Correcting these Growing Cooler insists that reductions in the
biases and misrepresentations reveals that growth of driving are needed so that trans-
compact development would be a wasteful portation will contribute its “fair share” of
and inefficient way of achieving greenhouse greenhouse gas reductions.43 But what is fair?
gas reductions. The report implies that, since transportation

6
accounts for a third of emissions, it should tracks emissions through 2050, yet it effective-
provide a third of total emission reductions. ly assumes technology will freeze after 2020,
This ignores the fact that emissions reductions barely a quarter of the way through the time-
can be achieved in other sectors much more horizon of the report. Accepting that this is
cheaply and easily, which would be far more unlikely greatly shrinks the imperative to
efficient for society. For example, the McKinsey reduce driving.
study found that more than half of the cost- Data buried in the back of Growing Cooler
effective opportunities for emission reductions suggest that, to the extent that reductions in
are in the electricity sector, while transporta- driving can contribute at all to greenhouse gas
tion offers only 15 percent of such opportuni- reductions, only a small share of that contri-
ties.44 Unless advocates of compact develop- bution will come from compact development.
ment can prove that their policies would cost The report evaluates four policies that togeth-
less than $50 per ton, proposals to reduce dri- er, it concludes, could reduce driving by 38
ving to meet emission-reduction targets are percent. Of those policies, the two smallest
almost certain to be cost-ineffective. reductions in driving come from increased
Even among transportation investments, investments in transit, which would reduce
Growing Cooler provides no evidence that driving by only 4.6 percent, and increased pop-
compact development is a cost-effective solu- ulation densities, which would reduce driving
tion to greenhouse gas emissions. Instead, it by 7.7 percent.
relies on a weak metaphor of a three-legged The greatest reduction in driving comes
stool, the legs being more fuel-efficient cars, from an assumption that fuel prices will rise at
alternative fuels, and reduced driving. The rates that are significantly faster than histori-
first two “legs” alone will not meet emission- cal levels (possibly through higher fuel taxes),
reduction targets, says the report, so we must which would reduce driving by 14.4 percent.
reduce driving.45 This is closely followed by a policy of reducing
The only evidence the report offers that the investments in new highways, which would
first two legs are insufficient is based on the increase the growth in congestion and reduce
corporate average fuel economy (CAFE) stan- driving by 11.4 percent.47
dard in the Energy Independence and Security In other words, two-thirds of the project-
Act of 2007, which called for increasing the ed reductions in driving come from making
average fuel economy of cars to 35 miles per driving more expensive, not from land-use
gallon by 2020. The report also accounts for a changes or investments in alternatives to dri-
federal requirement that alternative fuel use be ving. This reveals that compact-city policies
increased so as to reduce carbon dioxide emis- are far less effective than its proponents
sions by about 10 percent. The report shows imply, and that the compact-city agenda is
that the emission reductions from these two far more coercive—relying more on punitive
standards will be offset by increases in driving. pricing measures than changes to the built
Most of the
This leads to the conclusion that driving must environment—than its proponents admit. reductions in
be reduced.46 In an effort to show that its policies are not driving in
In effect, the report assumes that no fur- necessarily coercive, Growing Cooler argues that
ther increases in fuel efficiencies or alternative increasing numbers of Americans want to live Growing Cooler
fuels are possible beyond those in the 2007 in more compact cities. The report relies heav- come from
law. That assumption has already been proven ily on the projections of an urban planning policies that
obsolete, because in 2009 auto manufacturers professor named Arthur Nelson, who claims
accepted an even tighter CAFE standard of that by 2025 the United States will have a sur- make driving
35.5 mph by 2016. The report further assumes plus of single-family homes on large lots and more expensive,
that auto manufacturers will make no addi- all new construction will have to be multi-fam-
tional improvements in fuel efficiency or alter- ily housing or single-family homes on small
not from compact
native-fueled autos after 2020. Growing Cooler lots.48 development.

7
Those who However, Nelson himself is guilty of opti- Energy, single-family homes actually consume
believe we should mism bias. He claims that only 25 percent of less energy per square foot than multi-family
Americans want to live in single-family homes homes. Despite their shared walls, two- to
reduce carbon on large lots, while 37 percent want small lots four-unit multi-family homes use 25 percent
emissions should (less than one-sixth of an acre) and 38 percent more energy per square foot, while residences
prefer multi-family housing. These numbers, with five or more units use 8 percent more,
reject compact he says, are “based on interpretations of sur- than single-family detached homes.53
development as veys” reported by urban planners Dowell This means the Brookings study is really
expensive, risky, Myers and Elizabeth Gearin.49 Yet the Myers- proposing to save energy by forcing Americans
Gearin paper completely contradicts Nelson’s to drastically reduce the size of their living
and likely to “interpretation,” citing survey after survey spaces. Yet it is likely that technological
distract attention finding that 75 to 85 percent of Americans improvements—better insulation, designs that
from more aspire to live in single-family homes with a take better advantage of solar heating oppor-
yard.50 tunities, and so forth—could achieve far more
cost-effective If compact-city advocates truly believed in energy savings at a lower cost without requir-
emission- Nelson’s numbers, they would not need to use ing dramatic changes in lifestyles. Just as com-
regulation to increase densities of American pact-city advocates consider technological
reduction cities. Builders responding to market demand solutions that make driving more energy-effi-
programs. alone would make cities denser. But in fact, cient to be inadequate, the Brookings report
achieving Growing Cooler’s compact-city goals implicitly considers technological solutions
will require a degree of coercion from the fed- that make single-family housing more energy-
eral government that is unprecedented in efficient to be insufficient.
American history: limits on rural land devel-
opment, mandated changes to existing resi- Cost-Effective GHG Reductions
dential areas, and huge taxpayer-supported The Center for Clean Air Policy report
subsidies to entice people to live in higher-den- shares a co-author, Steve Winkelman, with
sity complexes. Growing Cooler—along with many of the latter
report’s arguments. But it also claims to prove
Shrinking the Carbon Footprint that compact development is a cost-effective
The Brookings Institution report is the means of reducing greenhouse gases. In fact,
only one considered in this paper that deals the report claims that reducing per capita dri-
with greenhouse gas emissions from sources ving by 10 percent “can be achieved profitably,
other than transportation. Not only will when factoring in avoided infrastructure
compact cities reduce driving, says the report, costs, consumer savings and projected tax rev-
but they will also reduce the energy con- enue growth.”54
sumption and greenhouse gas emissions Typically, the report offers almost no real-
from housing and other buildings. world data to support this conclusion. In-
Buildings, the report points out, account stead, it relies on the projections of urban plan-
for even more carbon emissions than trans- ners in Atlanta, Portland, Sacramento, and
portation—39 percent vs. 33 percent.51 The re- elsewhere for how their policies will affect ener-
port advocates compact development to re- gy consumption and other behaviors. Though
duce these costs through “smaller homes and it calls these “case studies,” the report’s argu-
shared walls in multi-unit dwellings.”52 ments suffer from optimism bias and strategic
As with Growing Cooler’s demand that we misrepresentations.55
reduce driving, the Brookings report fails to For example, CCAP reports that Sacramen-
show that compact development is a cost- to’s “smart-growth plan is projected to reduce
effective way of saving energy or reducing emissions [at] a net economic benefit of $198
greenhouse gases from residential or other per ton carbon dioxide.” Yet Sacramento has
buildings. According to the Department of been using smart-growth plans requiring com-

8
pact development and investments in transit land, the “initial project loan” is a $75 million
for decades, but the environmental gains from tax-increment financed subsidy to the develop-
these efforts seem to be minimal. The region’s ers.60 What CCAP does not reveal is that the tax
2006 plan openly admitted that its smart- revenues required to repay this subsidy would
growth plans imposed “during the past 25 otherwise go to schools and other essential
years have not worked out.” Despite building urban services for Atlantic Station.
light rail, the share of transit riders who “have The problem with relying on projections
access to an automobile [and] can otherwise rather than reality is that the projections are
choose to drive” is decreasing. Despite efforts often made by planners who themselves suffer
to promote compact development, both jobs from optimism bias and strategic misrepre-
and residences continued to decentralize. sentation. For example, planners typically por-
Despite the region’s failure to build new roads tray tax-increment financing as a way of “self-
to accommodate growth, “lack of road build- financing” economic development. Yet the
ing and the resulting congestion have not new development requires the same urban ser-
encouraged many people to take transit vices as existing development, but the taxes
instead of driving.”56 Despite the failure of past that would have gone to those services are
plans, Sacramento adopted a plan that contin- transferred to the developers instead.
ued these failed policies and projected benefits In most cases, subsidies to economic devel-
CCAP’s claims
that were based more on hope than experience. opment are, at best, a zero-sum game: if plan- that compact
The CCAP report breathlessly notes “that ners subsidize it to take place in a dense sec- development is
$73 million invested in the Portland Streetcar tion of a city, it will not take place somewhere
helped attract $2.3 billion in private invest- else. So planners cannot claim the benefits of “cost effective”
ment within two blocks of the line.”57 What it that development as a net gain for the city or are based on
does not say is that, at the same time that it region; in fact, the tax subsidy is a net loss. At
built the streetcar line, Portland spent more worst, such subsidies are a negative-sum
projects in which
than $665 million subsidizing new develop- game: by increasing taxes or reducing urban cities effectively
ments along the line, including building park- services, they discourage employers from steal money from
ing garages for retailers, subsidizing an aerial moving to or remaining in the region. As a
tram, parks, and parking garages for a devel- study in Illinois found, communities that use schools, fire,
opment near the Oregon Health Sciences tax-increment financing actually “grow more and police to
University, and providing 10 years of property- slowly than those that do not.”61 subsidize
tax waivers to many residences that were built In Sacramento and Portland, at least, tax
along the streetcar line.58 increases ordinarily require voter approval. developers.
Except for the property-tax waivers, most But tax-increment financing is exempt from
of these subsidies came from tax-increment this requirement. Far from being profitable,
financing, which effectively transfers tax rev- cities that use tax-increment financing to sup-
enues from schools, fire, police, and other port compact development are effectively
essential services to property developers. Far stealing from schoolchildren, firefighters, and
from being “profitable,” as CCAP claims, other recipients and providers of urban ser-
such transfers give residents a choice between vices—and, in turn, stealing from the taxpayers
declining urban services and higher taxes to who agreed to fund those services.
replace the funds lost to schools and other
urban services. Moving Cooler
CCAP claims that the Atlanta development While Moving Cooler is in many ways a
Atlantic Station will reduce greenhouse gas sequel to Growing Cooler, it maintains a patina
emissions “at a net cost savings, because mu- of greater objectivity because it was written by
nicipal tax revenues from the project will be a consulting firm, Cambridge Systematics,
greater than what is required to pay back the rather than by employees of organizations that
initial project loan.”59 As in the case of Port- have supported compact development for two

9
decades. Yet Moving Cooler relies on many of the duce 1.5 billion metric tons of greenhouse
same sources as Growing Cooler, and back- gas reductions. This seems questionable con-
ground documents specifically cite Growing sidering that transit produces about the
Cooler as the source of many of the new report’s same amount of greenhouse gases per pas-
assumptions. senger mile as automobiles.69
For example, Moving Cooler uses Arthur To reach this conclusion, Cambridge Sys-
Nelson’s projections, “as cited in Growing tematics assumed that new technologies
Cooler,” of the future demand for various types would reduce greenhouse gas emissions per
of housing.62 It based its estimate of the reduc- passenger mile from buses by 26 percent and
tions in driving due to “pedestrian-friendly from rail transit by 50 percent or more, even if
environments” on a paper by Ewing (a Growing passenger loadings remain about the same as
Cooler co-author) and Cervero, “also cited in they are today.70 This is extremely unlikely,
Growing Cooler.”63 particularly for rail transit. America’s automo-
Cambridge Systematics also relied on a bile fleet turns over every 18 years, so by 2050
paper by the Center for Clean Air Policy for we will have two completely new generations
nearly all of its numbers relating to high-speed of automobiles on the roads, many of which
rail.64 This paper contained many examples of will be lighter and have less wind- and rolling-
optimism bias and strategic misrepresenta- resistance than today’s cars. But rail transit
tion. For example, the paper assumed that fleets turn over only once every 30 to 40 years,
high-speed trains would operate 70 percent and there is little reason to think that future
full.65 Yet Amtrak trains in 2008—a banner vehicles will be significantly more fuel-effi-
year for passenger trains due to high gas cient than the ones on the rails today.71
prices—were only 52 percent full.66 Moreover, both bus and rail transit vehicles
Unlike most of the other reports considered are significantly less fuel efficient, per passen-
here, Moving Cooler compares compact develop- ger mile, today than they were in 1980.72 This
ment with other ways of reducing vehicle-relat- is mainly due to a decline in passenger load-
ed greenhouse gas emissions, including park- ings that has resulted from expansions of ser-
ing and highway pricing, carbon taxes, ride- vice into areas that make little use of transit.
sharing and similar commuting strategies, Cambridge Systematics’ assumption that a
It is more intelligent transportation systems, and high- huge expansion of transit service will not re-
cost-effective way capacity expansions.67 Though the report duce average passenger loads is likely to be
to dedicate estimates the costs and emission reductions optimistic.
from “expanded,” “aggressive,” and “maxi- The one way in which transit expansions
renewable energy mum” levels of each strategy, it does not take could significantly reduce greenhouse gas
to electric cars the next step of calculating the cost per ton of emissions is if the transit were powered by
abatements. non-fossil-fuel sources of electricity. But it
and plug-in Those costs range from pennies to $5,900 would be more cost-effective to dedicate such
hybrids, which per ton. Of 47 strategies considered, only 21 electricity to electric cars and plug-in hybrids,
can be recharged are estimated to cost $50 per ton or less, and which can be recharged overnight when elec-
in some cases the cost is less than $50 at only tricity demand is low, and allow daytime use
overnight when some levels of implementation. For example, of that electricity for other purposes.
electricity “expanded incident management” costs $37 Even with Cambridge Systematics’ gener-
per ton, but “maximum incident manage- ous assumptions regarding improvements in
demand is low, ment” costs $161 per ton.68 transit efficiencies, the cost of the maximum
then to use it Even though the report provides readers transit expansions is more than $2,000 per
for transit in with enough data to calculate costs per ton, ton, while the cost of lesser expansions exceeds
many of the cost and benefit estimates are $1,700 per ton. This is far more than can be
daytime, when questionable. For example, maximum expan- considered cost-effective under the McKinsey
demand is high. sions of transit service are estimated to pro- report’s guideline of $50 per ton.

10
According to Moving Cooler, compact-devel- with two scenarios: one in which 25 percent of A literature
opment strategies are very cost-effective, rang- all future urban development is built to twice review by
ing from $1 to $9 per ton. But the costs pro- the existing urban densities and one in which
jected by Cambridge Systematics are extremely 75 percent is built to twice the current densi- University of
low. It claims that compact development ties. The report arbitrarily assumed that resi- California
nationwide would cost the same $1.5 billion dents of compact developments would drive
under the expanded (43 percent of new devel- 12 percent less than average under the 25-per-
economist David
opment is compact), aggressive (64 percent), cent scenario and 25 percent less than average Brownstone
and maximum (90 percent) levels of deploy- under the 75-percent scenario.76 This is partic- found that the
ment of compact city policies.73 At apparently ularly optimistic considering that the report’s
no extra cost, the maximum level is projected own literature review found driving reductions link between
to reduce greenhouse gas emissions by more of just 3 to 20 percent. the built
than 9 times the expanded level. Based on these assumptions, the report pro- environment and
This report will show that compact devel- jects that total miles of driving would be 1 per-
opment will cost far more than $1.5 billion. cent less than the base case under the 25-per- driving is “too
But even under the maximum level, Cam- cent scenario, and up to 11 percent less under small to be
bridge Systematics estimates that compact the 75-percent scenario. The report adds that
development will reduce greenhouse gas emis- “the committee disagreed about whether the
useful.”
sions by just 38 million tons in 2030, or about changes in development patterns and public
a half a percent of current U.S. emissions. By policies necessary to achieve the high end of
2050 this would increase to 73 tons, or about these findings are plausible.”77
1.3 percent of current emissions.74 In preparing this report, the committee
commissioned five background papers. Most
Driving and the Built Environment of these papers offer little support to those
The Transportation Research Board report, who promote compact development as a way
Driving and the Built Environment: The Effects of of reducing greenhouse gas emissions.
Compact Development on Motorized Travel, Energy One paper by University of California econ-
Use, and Carbon Dioxide Emissions, has an even omist David Brownstone reviewed the litera-
stronger claim to objectivity than Moving Cool- ture on relationships between “the built envi-
er. The report was written under the supervi- ronment” and driving (as measured by vehicle
sion of a 12-member committee that included miles traveled, or VMT). He concluded that
a mix of planners and transportation engi- there is a “statistically significant link” between
neers. Some members of the committee—most the built environment and VMT—but that the
notably Dianne Brake of PlanSmart NJ, An- available evidence suggests “the size of this link
drew Cotugno of Metro (Portland’s metropol- is too small to be useful.”78 Brownstone also
itan planning organization), and Rolf Pendall wonders “why controlling VMT should be a
of the Cornell University City and Regional policy goal,” since mobility has a high value and
Planning Department—have been unabashed evidence suggests that people respond to high-
supporters of compact development, but oth- er fuel prices by buying more fuel-efficient cars
ers have been more skeptical. more than by reducing driving.79
“Evidence from the literature,” says the A paper by transportation engineer Kara
report, indicates “doubling density is associat- Kockelman (who was also on the TRB com-
ed with about 5 percent less VMT [vehicle mittee) and colleagues at the University of
miles traveled] on average.” When “other land- Texas reviews alternative means of reducing
use factors” such as mixed uses and pedestri- greenhouse gas emissions. The paper con-
an-friendly design are taken into account, cludes that policies emphasizing higher fuel-
“reports find that VMT is lower by an average economy standards will be much more cost-
of 3 to 20 percent.”75 effective at reducing emissions than land-use
The report compares a base case (no action) policies aimed at reducing driving. In fact, the

11
paper says, compact development and transit house emissions is a highly risky proposition.
improvements could both substantially in- There is no consensus among researchers
crease emissions rather than reduce them—the about how much compact development would
first by increasing congestion (which leads reduce driving, and the 25-percent reduction
cars to emit more pollution) and the second assumed by Driving and the Built Environment’s
because transit construction and operations 75-percent scenario is outside the range of lit-
both emit substantial amounts of greenhouse erature reviewed by the report. Claims that
gases.80 demand for compact development is increas-
George Mason University transportation ing also appear overstated, and there are
engineer Michael Bronzini wrote a paper on numerous uncertainties about the benefits
the relationship between land use and truck and costs of such policies as concentrating em-
traffic. He concluded that “low-density devel- ployment and construction of transit improve-
opment does increase truck traffic” and that ments. These risks suggest that all the various
“it appears that smart-growth measures could compact-development reports are likely to
be effective in reducing truck VMT.”81 How- have overstated the benefits and underestimat-
ever, Bronzini did not assess the cost-effective- ed the costs of compact-city policies.
ness of such measures.
There is no A paper on housing trends by John Pitkin
consensus among and Dowell Myers seriously questions Arthur Overstating the Benefits
researchers Nelson’s claims that cities should be substan-
tially rebuilt at higher densities to meet the Growing Cooler says its policies can reduce
about how much demand for those densities. “Nelson and oth- the growth rate of driving by 38 percent.85
compact ers have placed too great an emphasis on Moving Cooler says that smart-growth policies
development changing preferences as the driver of changing can reduce total greenhouse gas emissions by
development patterns,” says the paper. The 9 to 15 percent.86 In fact, a close reading of
would reduce report found “scant evidence of any net shift these and other reports reveals that compact
driving, of total or elderly population toward central development has minimal effects on driving
cities,” where development is typically dens- and greenhouse gas emissions.
suggesting this is er.82 Where Nelson projected that changes in
a highly risky tastes would lead to substantial reconstruc- • Growing Cooler found that building 60
proposition. tion of urban areas, Pitkin and Myers expect percent of new urban development to
“lower replacement rates” and more reliance compact standards would reduce 2030
on existing housing.83 This suggests that gov- carbon dioxide outputs by 79 million
ernment mandates to rebuild urban areas to tons, or 1.3 percent of current levels.87
higher densities will be far more expensive • Moving Cooler was far less optimistic,
than suggested by compact-city advocates. projecting that building 64 percent of
A paper by urban planner Genevieve Giuli- new development to compact standards,
ano and colleagues at UCLA concludes that including more pedestrian- and bicycle-
two-thirds to three-fourths of jobs in modern friendly design and “high-quality tran-
urban areas are not located either in down- sit,” would reduce 2030 carbon dioxide
towns or other urban and suburban centers; outputs by only 22 million tons, or less
instead, they are finely dispersed throughout than 0.4 percent of current emissions.
urban areas. This suggests that concentrating • Moving Cooler’s maximum effort of mak-
employment, one of the goals of compact-city ing 90 percent of new development com-
advocates, will be expensive. The paper also pact would reduce 2030 greenhouse gas
expresses doubt that accomplishing this goal emissions by 0.6 percent, and 2050 emis-
will have significant effects on driving.84 sions by 1.2 percent below current levels.
Taken together, these papers suggest that • Driving and the Built Environment project-
using compact development to reduce green- ed that building 75 percent of new devel-

12
opment to twice current densities would admits that increasing the cost of auto dri-
reduce 2050 driving by 11 percent, there- ving, through taxes and congestion, has a far
by reducing greenhouse gas emissions greater effect on driving than compact devel-
by, at most, 1.4 percent below current opment and transit improvements. Moreover,
levels. note that Growing Cooler does not project that
compact development will reduce emissions,
The similarity between the Moving Cooler only that it reduces the growth in driving—and
and Driving and the Built Environment estimates then only by 7.7 percent.
disguises a huge debate among urban planners Moving Cooler’s claim that “smart growth”
and economists over how much differences in could reduce greenhouse emissions by 9 to
driving are due to the “built environment” and 15 percent is based on a “bundling” of com-
how much are due to “self selection.” Many pact development with other policies, includ-
studies have found that people who live in ing taxes on existing parking, a freeze on all
dense, mixed-use areas drive less than people in new parking, HOV lanes, urban nonmotor-
low-density suburbs, but it is likely that a large ized zones, and mandates that employers
part of this is because people who want to dri- alter their employees’ commuting habits.92
ve less choose to live in dense, mixed-use neigh- While Moving Cooler claims there are synergis-
borhoods with intensive transit service. tic effects between these policies, it never ver-
Growing Cooler dismissed this concern by ifies this claim by comparing the implemen-
citing a literature review of studies of the effects tation of these other policies with and
of density and urban design on driving. without the compact-development policies.
“Virtually every quantitative study reviewed for Compact-development advocates are so
this work,” the literature review is quoted as intent on seeing their policies implemented
saying, “found a statistically significant influ- that they never objectively assess the cost-
ence of one or more built environment mea- effectiveness of those policies by themselves.
sures on the travel behavior.”88 Growing Cooler A careful look reveals that compact-city pro-
neglected to quote the very next sentence of the grams contemplated by these reports could
literature review: “However, the practical cost Americans trillions of dollars.
importance of that influence was seldom
assessed.”89 In other words, “statistically signif- Compact-
icant” does not mean “large”; it only means Underestimating the Costs development
“measurable.” As David Brownstone’s litera-
ture review for TRB concluded, the effects While advocates of reducing greenhouse advocates are so
themselves are likely to be “too small to be use- gas emissions might argue that every little bit intent on seeing
ful” in reducing greenhouse gas emissions.90 helps, the truth is that it only helps if it is cost- their policies
Even if the effects projected by these efficient; cost-inefficient investments would
reports are realistic, they hardly make the effectively crowd out cost-efficient programs implemented
case for implementing compact-develop- and make it more difficult to achieve reduc- that they never
ment policies. As one reviewer of the TRB tion targets. Yet the cost of compact develop-
report concluded, “increasing population ment is likely to be extremely high.
objectively
density in metropolitan areas would yield The Moving Cooler report inexplicably assess the cost-
insignificant carbon dioxide reductions.”91 claims that compact development will cost a effectiveness of
But if they are so insignificant, how can the mere $1.5 billion no matter whether 43 per-
authors of so many of these reports argue cent, 64 percent, or 90 percent of new devel- those policies,
that compact development policies are essen- opment is compact. But at least one member which could cost
tial or that they can reduce emissions by 9 to of the TRB committee believes costs will be
15 percent? much higher. “It’s an enormous amount of
Americans
One way is by conflating compact develop- effort to achieve a tiny amount of outcome,” trillions of
ment with other policies. Growing Cooler says Brookings Institution researcher An- dollars.

13
Portland’s thony Downs, regarding the TRB 75-percent panded, planners have placed so many obsta-
mayor supports scenario. “If your principal goal is to reduce cles to home construction that it appears the
fuel emissions, I don’t think future growth new areas will never be developed.97
putting 300,000 density is the way to do it.”93 To accommodate growth without expand-
new residents in Here are some of the costs that compact- ing boundaries, Portland-area planners have
city mandates will impose on Americans: rezoned dozens of neighborhoods of single-
high-density family homes for apartments, using zoning so
developments • Loss of property rights strict that if someone’s house burns down, they
“within one- • Reduced geographic mobility will be required to replace it with an apart-
• Higher housing costs and lower home- ment.98 Portland’s mayor, Samuel Adams, sup-
quarter mile of all ownership rates ports putting all new residents—an estimated
existing and • Higher taxes or reduced urban services 300,000 by 2035—in high-density transit-ori-
to-be-planned to subsidize compact development ented developments “within one-quarter mile
• Increased traffic congestion of all existing and to-be-planned streetcar and
streetcar and • Higher consumer costs light-rail transit stops.”99
light-rail transit • Reduced economic mobility Naturally, these sorts of policies generate
stiff resistance from rural property owners
stops.” Property Rights who do not want their land “downzoned” and
States that have attempted to use compact urban homeowners who do not want their
development to reduce driving have engaged neighborhoods “densified.” Considering the
in a substantial amount of coercion, much of uncertainty about whether compact develop-
which is aimed at limiting the property rights ment can even have a significant effect on
of private landowners. In 1991, Oregon’s land- greenhouse gas emissions, this sort of contro-
use planning commission required metropoli- versy is bound to distract attention from the
tan planners to use land-use tools to reduce more serious debate over whether, and by how
per capita driving by 20 percent.94 To reach much, emissions should be reduced—a dis-
this goal, the state severely limits what private traction that emissions-reduction advocates
landowners can do in rural areas, while it man- should want to avoid.
dates high-density development on private Compact-city advocates argue that zoning
land in urban areas. that prevents developers from building apart-
For example, private landowners in rural ments in neighborhoods of single-family
Oregon are allowed to build a house on their homes is itself a restriction on property rights
own land only if they own at least 80 acres, that should be lifted. But such zoning was
they actually farm it, and they earn at least originally put in place to protect property val-
$80,000 per year from farming it. The state’s ues. In the absence of zoning, developers have
land-use agency is proud that only about 100 found that sale prices are enhanced when they
homes per year have been built in rural areas place covenants on properties that prevent the
since this rule was adopted in 1993.95 Nearly mixture of single-family housing with other
98 percent of the state has been zoned “rural” uses. Historically, most zoning of undevelop-
or some similarly restrictive zone.96 ed areas has been responsive to market de-
Meanwhile, about 1.25 percent of the state mand. Once developed, zoning aims to pro-
has been classified as “urban,” or inside of an tect existing property values, and as such it is
urban-growth boundary. (The remaining 1 merely an alternative to such covenants. Com-
percent is zoned “rural residential,” meaning 5 pact-city zoning is far more prescriptive, often
to 10 acre minimum lot sizes.) While some mandating unmarketable changes to existing
cities have expanded their growth boundaries uses that can significantly reduce property val-
in response to population growth, Portland is ues, at least for the current owners.
instead intent on “growing up, not out.” Even A case can be made that zoning restrictions
where the Portland boundary has been ex- should be relaxed so that developers can meet

14
the market demand for higher-density hous- car, but transit ridership grew by only 700 mil-
ing. But relaxing restrictions is very different lion passenger miles, or less than 3 percent of
from imposing tighter restrictions that man- the drop in urban auto travel.103
date high-density housing. Even when relax- Even to the extent that transit can replace
ing restrictions, property owners should be auto trips, the cost is very high. Counting all
given the opportunity to form homeowner capital and operating costs, including subsi-
associations that can write protective cov- dies, Americans spend about 24 cents per pas-
enants that will protect their neighborhood’s senger mile on auto travel.104 By comparison,
property values, as has been suggested by urban transit costs an average of 81 cents per
University of Maryland professor Robert Nel- passenger mile.105 Nor is it likely that these
son.100 costs will decline if transit use increases. More
than 40 percent of all American transit rider-
Mobility ship is in the New York metropolitan area, but
Americans are the most mobile people on New York transit operating costs per trip or
earth, and that mobility is an important part passenger mile are only about 20 percent less
of America’s economic well-being. Research than the national average.
has proven that there is a strong correlation
between mobility and economic productivity. Housing
Mass
Regions in which workers can reach more jobs Planners create compact cities by using transportation is
within a 25-minute commute, or employers urban-growth boundaries or similar tools not an adequate
have access to more workers within 25 min- that create artificial land shortages. Given
utes, grow faster and provide higher incomes the resulting high land prices, higher per- substitute for
than less mobile regions.101 centages of home buyers settle for multi-fam- automobility, as
Contrary to implications often made by ily housing where they might have preferred
compact-city advocates, transit is not an ade- single family, or settle for small lots where
it tends to be slow
quate substitute for automobility. Even the they might have preferred large yards. and doesn’t go
best public transit systems in the world are In short, compact-development policies where people
slower, reach fewer destinations, and fail to greatly increase the costs of all types of housing
go at all times when automobiles can be as well as retail, commercial, and industrial want to go when
available. This is revealed by comparing trav- development. States that have required cities to they want to
el in Europe with that in the United States. write compact-development plans have signifi- go there.
In 2004, the average American traveled more cantly less affordable housing than states that
than 15,000 miles by auto, compared with do not.106 Such states also suffered from the
6,600 miles for the average western European worst housing bubbles in the recent financial
(residents of the fifteen countries in the crisis, while states that did not require such
European Union in 2000). Meanwhile, the aver- plans tended not to have any bubbles.107
age European traveled less than 1,300 miles by Arguably, at least some of these higher
bus and rail compared with more than 600 costs are a zero-sum game: for every land or
miles by the average American.102 The 700 addi- homebuyer who must pay more, there is a
tional miles of bus and rail travel hardly make seller who earns a windfall profit because of
up for the 8,800 fewer miles of auto travel. the artificial shortage. But at least some of
When gasoline prices briefly reached $4 per the costs are a deadweight loss to society.
gallon in 2008, numerous media reports indi- For example, in regions with no urban-
cated that Americans were driving less and growth mandates, cities and counties compete
taking transit more. Yet the increases in transit for new development, and the tax revenues
usage actually made up for only a tiny percent that it brings in, by keeping permitting costs
of the decline in driving. In the second quarter low and approval times short. Urban-growth
of 2008, for example, Americans traveled 25 boundaries limit this competition, and cities
billion fewer passenger miles in urban areas by typically respond by significantly increasing

15
permit costs and the risk that property owners neyland for yuppies” (as California demogra-
will never get a permit to build. One study pher Hans Johnson put it) or “boutique cities
found that such policies increased permitting catering only to a small, highly educated elite”
costs from $10,000 per home in relatively (as Harvard economist Edward Glaeser put
unregulated Dallas to $100,000 per home in it).114 While that might be good for the
San Jose, which adopted compact-develop- region’s short-term tax revenues, it slows eco-
ment policies in 1974.108 nomic growth and reduces the opportunities
Many cities have responded to the hous- for economic mobility that are available to
ing affordability problems created by their low-income families in more affordable hous-
compact-development policies by mandating ing markets.
that developers sell 10 to 20 percent of their
homes at below-market prices to low-income Taxes and Urban Services
buyers. This leads to developers to both raise Creating artificial land shortages that
the price of other homes to make up for the boost housing costs is not enough for com-
losses on the share they must sell below mar- pact-city planners in many regions. Most cities
ket and to build fewer homes, which creates have supplemented this with subsidies to
further affordability problems.109 high-density, mixed-use developments that
Growing Cooler and Moving Cooler rely on supposedly reduce driving. The biggest source
Arthur Nelson’s estimate that 89 million new of these subsidies is probably tax-increment
or replaced homes will be built between now financing, which was discussed under the
and 2050.110 If 80 percent of this construction CCAP report.
takes place in metropolitan areas and suffers a Other subsidies include property-tax
deadweight cost of $25,000 per housing unit waivers for favored kinds of development,
because of compact-development policies, the below-market sales of public land to develop-
cost will reach nearly $1.7 trillion. ers who promise to build at certain densities,
Even to the extent that someone gains and public financing of infrastructure that
when others are forced to pay higher prices for would otherwise have been built by the devel-
homes and land, the economy as a whole loses oper. Many cities also streamline approval
for several reasons. First, less affordable hous- processes and/or waive impact fees for denser
ing tends to mean lower homeownership developments.
rates. Studies show many positive benefits While Moving Cooler estimates that the total
associated with homeownership. For example, cost of increasing the density of 90 percent of
children in low-income families that own their all new urban development in the United
own homes do significantly better in school States would be just $1.5 billion, Portland
than those in low-income families that rent.111 alone has committed nearly this amount in
Areas with high rates of rental housing are subsidies to developers of high-density pro-
By making traditionally associated with higher unem- jects. The city has committed more than $230
housing more ployment rates. But research has found that million in subsidies to the famous Pearl
compact-city policies can reverse this relation- District (River District) and nearly $290 mil-
expensive, ship. Artificial shortages of housing increase lion in subsidies to the South Waterfront
compact- the costs of selling and moving, and so dis- District (North Macadam), both of which are
development courage people who own their own homes on the streetcar line; more than $300 million
from relocating to a city with more jobs.112 to the Interstate Corridor on the Yellow light-
policies are likely Urban areas that make themselves unaf- rail line; more than $164 million for the
to impose a fordable using compact-city policies end up Gateway District on the Blue light-rail line;
with dramatically different income distribu- $75 million for the Lents District on the Green
deadweight cost tions from the rest of the country.113 Low- and light-rail line; more than $72 million for
on society of at even middle-income families are forced to Airport Way on the Red light-rail line; and $66
least $1.7 trillion. move out, turning the urban area into “Dis- million to the Central Eastside District, on a

16
planned streetcar and light-rail line.115 This to limit the “expansion of roadways” in the Compact
only counts tax-increment financed subsidies hope that “as traffic congestion builds, alter- development
and not tax waivers, below-market land sales, native travel modes will become more attrac-
or other subsidies. tive.”117 increases traffic
As described above, projects supported Similarly, Portland decided to allow rush- congestion
through tax-increment financing and prop- hour congestion to reach “level of service F” (a
erty-tax waivers increase the burdens on traffic engineering term meaning stop-and-go
because large
Portland schools, fire, police, public health, traffic) in most of the city’s highways. When increases in
and other programs, but dedicate the taxes asked why, transportation planner Andrew densities are
that would have gone to those programs to Cotugno (who was a member of the TRB com-
developers instead. The result is that these mittee) responded that relieving congestion required to get
other programs have seen declines in both “would eliminate transit ridership.”118 small reductions
the quality and quantity of services they can Even if congestion were not a deliberate in per capita
provide to the rest of the city. goal of compact-city planners, it would clearly
In many cases, Portland subsidies have be a major result of such plans. Using census driving.
exceeded $100,000 per housing unit. If subsi- data, Moving Cooler estimated that increasing
dies averaging $25,000 per housing unit are densities from an average of 3,000 people per
applied to 60 percent of the new homes built square mile by an additional 133 percent to an
in metropolitan areas between now and 2050, average of 7,000 people would reduce per capi-
the total subsidies will exceed $1 trillion. This ta driving by less than 15 percent.119 That
assumes 89 million new homes built between many more people driving 15-percent less
now and 2050, as estimated by Arthur Nelson, each still means a 100-percent increase in total
80 percent of which would be within metro- vehicle miles of travel. Since compact-city
politan areas. But the Pitkin and Myers paper planners would oppose any new highways to
commissioned for the TRB study calculates accommodate that travel, there would obvi-
that Nelson overestimated the rate of new ously be a huge increase in congestion.
construction by 50 percent, which means sub- Congestion, of course, imposes huge costs
sidies would have to be even greater to reach on commuters and businesses. It also impacts
compact-development targets.116 the environment, as autos in stop-and-go traf-
Combined, the deadweight losses from fic consume far more fuel and emit more pol-
compact-development regulations and subsi- lution and greenhouse gases per mile than
dies are likely to exceed $2.8 trillion. If these reg- autos in free-flowing traffic. In fact, the focus
ulations and subsidies produce the maximum on reducing miles of driving is misguided
reductions in greenhouse gas emissions pro- because miles driven are not proportional to
jected by Moving Cooler, the cost per ton of abat- greenhouse gas emissions, since congestion is
ed emissions will be nearly $2,000—well above the leading cause of such disproportionality.
the $50-per-ton cost-effectiveness threshold set
by the McKinsey report. Of course, this does Consumer Costs
not count other costs of compact development, Compact development advocates often
such as congestion and effects on consumer argue that the loss of mobility resulting from
prices. less auto driving can be mitigated by increased
accessibility from mixing retail and other uses
Congestion with, or within walking distance of, residential
Increasing roadway congestion appears to areas. Why drive when you can simply walk
be a deliberate part of compact-city plans. If downstairs from your condo and go grocery
people cannot easily travel long distances, shopping or have a cup of coffee? “Millions of
planners hope, they will be more willing to live people could be liberated from their vehicles”
in denser developments. In 1996, for example, if neighborhoods were redesigned to make
the Twin Cities Metropolitan Council decided things accessible without requiring mobility,

17
argues Robert Cervero (who was on the TRB vehicle for most people, poor or not poor,”
committee).120 says UCLA planning professor Genevieve
This ignores, however, the nature of the Giuliano.124 For example, an analysis of job
modern retail industry. Major supermarkets accessibility in Cincinnati found that people
and other stores can offer a wide variety of living in low-income neighborhoods could
low-cost goods only because large numbers of reach 99 percent of the region’s jobs within 20
customers can reach them by car. Shrink the minutes by car, but only 21 percent of the
pool of customers by limiting them to those region’s jobs in a 40-minute trip by transit.
within walking distance and costs rise—while Furthermore, building light rail, the study
the variety of goods offered declines. Prices rise found, would actually reduce job accessibility
further when people become captives of one for low-income workers.125
store; the competition that exists when people Economic mobility is the American dream,
can reach several stores in one short auto trip and geographic mobility is a key component
encourages retailers to adopt innovative pro- of that dream. No matter how noble the inten-
grams that reduce costs. tions, proposals to reduce mobility should be
Moreover, like homebuyers, retailers in viewed with the same suspicion as proposals
compact communities will have to pay more to reduce freedom of speech or freedom of the
Mobility is a key for land, adding further to consumer prices. press.
component of the Thus, the higher prices that are typically
American dream, found in “accessible” versus mobile communi-
ties are not a zero-sum game: the retailers are Getting the Prices Right
and proposals to not earning fatter profits; they are merely suf-
reduce mobility fering higher costs due to inefficient manage- Compact development is an indirect and
ment. risky way of reducing greenhouse gas emis-
should be viewed sions. It depends on people responding to
with the same Economic Mobility compact cities in the ways that planners
suspicion as Several studies have found that auto own- hope; on the assumption that reduced green-
ership is a key factor to helping low-income house gas emissions from reduced driving
proposals to limit families move into the middle class. One will not be offset by increased emissions from
freedom of speech found that people without a high-school more driving in stop-and-go traffic; and on
or freedom of diploma were 80 percent more likely to have a planners’ faith that the costs of unintended
job and earned $1,100 more per month if they (and intended) consequences such as unaf-
religion. had a car. In fact, the study found that owning fordable housing, congestion, and reduced
a car was more helpful to getting a job than worker productivities will not be greater than
getting a high-school-equivalent degree.121 the benefits.
Another study found that closing the black- Those who are skeptical of the need to
white auto ownership gap would close nearly reduce carbon dioxide emissions should natu-
half the black-white employment gap.122 rally reject compact-city schemes as an unnec-
As a result, numerous analysts have noted essary and expensive imposition on personal
that efforts to reduce per capita driving will freedom and mobility. Those who support
have their greatest impact on low-income policies to reduce carbon dioxide emissions
families. “Their most severe effects” of mobil- should also reject compact-development pro-
ity restrictions, says Alan Pisarski, “will fall grams as risky, cost-ineffective ideas that will
on those groups that either have recently divert resources and attention away from gen-
attained mobility or are just now on the verge uine emission-reduction programs.
of attaining it.”123 One of the most effective ways of reducing
Transit improvements will not make up for carbon emissions is simply to price them
this loss in economic mobility. “Public transit using a revenue-neutral carbon tax whose
is not a reasonable substitute for the private income is offset by reductions in income or

18
other taxes. Moving Cooler estimates that car- one more source of pork barrel (as seems to The Brookings
bon pricing would be 10 times more effective have happened to the recent cap-and-trade study proposes
at reducing auto-related emissions than com- proposal). If climate change worries prove
pact development, and that the vast majority baseless, a carbon tax is not even necessary. to save energy
of that reduction would come from people But for those who insist on reducing carbon by drastically
buying more fuel-efficient cars, not driving emissions, a true, revenue-neutral carbon tax
less.126 makes far more sense than intrusive govern-
reducing the size
Carbon pricing would allow people to ment policies aimed at coercing people out of of American
choose for themselves whether they respond their homes and cars and forcing them to live living spaces.
to higher fuel prices by buying more fuel-effi- in politically correct multi-family housing
cient cars, using alternative fuels, “eco-dri- and to ride on politically correct mass transit.
ving” in a more fuel-efficient manner, or dri-
ving less. Those who choose to drive less
could also decide whether they want to live in Notes
high-density communities or continue to live 1. Reid Ewing, Keith Bartholomew, Steve Winkel-
in low-density communities but adjust other man, Jerry Walters, and Don Chen, Growing Cooler:
driving habits, perhaps by living closer to The Evidence on Urban Development and Climate
work, trip chaining, or shopping at one-stop Change (Washington: Urban Land Institute, 2008),
p. 1.
supercenters instead of several smaller stores.
Carbon pricing would also have more 2. Ibid.
immediate effects on energy use and carbon
emissions than compact development, which 3. Marilyn Brown, Frank Southworth, and Andrea
Sarzynski, “Shrinking the Carbon Footprint of Met-
will take decades to implement. Moving Cooler ropolitan America,” Brookings Institute, 2008, p. 3.
predicts that, in 2020, maximum use of car-
bon pricing would reduce auto-related emis- 4. Moving Cooler: An Analysis of Transportation Strat-
sions more than 30 times as much as maxi- egies for Reducing Greenhouse Gas Emissions (Washing-
ton: Urban Land Institute, 2009), pp. 2–3.
mum use of compact development, while in
2030 it would be 12 times as much.127 5. Steve Winkelman, Allison Bishins, and Chuck
These more-immediate effects mean that Kooshian, “Cost-Effective GHG Reductions
carbon pricing would be easier to evaluate and through Smart Growth and Improved Transpor-
tation Choices,” Center for Clean Air Policy, 2009,
fine-tune in order to ensure that any emission- p. 1.
reduction targets are met. By comparison, the
slow deployment of compact development, 6. Driving and the Built Environment: The Effects of
combined with the indirect effects it has on Compact Development on Motorized Travel, Energy
Use, and Carbon Dioxide Emissions (Washington:
driving and carbon emissions, means that National Research Council, 2009), p. 96.
decades will pass and hundreds of billions of
dollars will be spent before we know if it is 7. “HUD and DOT Partnership: Sustainable Com-
even working. munities,” Department of Transportation, Wash-
ington, DC, March 18, 2009, tinyurl.com/cbfxs4.
Finally, carbon pricing would not only be
easier to implement than compact develop- 8. Alan Wirzbicki, “LaHood Defends Mass Transit
ment, it would affect all producers of carbon Push,” Boston Globe, May 21, 2009, tinyurl.com/
emissions, notably including fossil-fuel-pow- ovszpq.
ered electrical plants. This means one tool can 9. Peter Geoffrey Hall, Cities of Tomorrow: An Intel-
address far more sources of carbon emissions, lectual History of Urban Planning and Design in the
while compact development mainly influ- Twentieth Century (Cambridge, MA: Blackwell, 2002
ences urban auto driving, which produces less edition), p. 79.
than 13 percent of greenhouse gases. 10. Ibid., p. 5.
No policy is immune to political abuse,
and carbon taxes could easily turn into just 11. Ibid., p. 244.

19
12. Ibid., p. 246. Sprawl Reconsidered: What the Data Really Show,”
Backgrounder no. 1770, June 25, 2004, p. 10.
13. Ibid., pp. 256–259.
29. Jan Brueckner and Ann Largey, “Social Inter-
14. Jane Jacobs, The Death and Life of Great American action and Urban Sprawl,” Center for Economic
Cities (New York: Vintage, 1963), p. 3. Studies/Ifo Institute, Working Paper no. 1843,
2006, p. 1.
15. George Dantzig and Thomas Saaty, Compact
City: A Plan for a Liveable Urban Environment (San 30. Robert Putnam, Bowling Alone: The Collapse and
Francisco: Freeman, 1973), p. 9. Revival of American Community (New York: Simon
and Schuster, 2000), p. 206.
16. Ibid., p. 26.
31. Reid Ewing, Tom Schmid, Richard Killings-
17. Andrés Duany and Elizabeth Plater-Zyberk, worth, Amy Zlot, and Stephen Raudenbush,
“The Second Coming of the American Small “Relationship between Urban Sprawl and Physical
Town,” Wilson’s Quarterly, Winter 1992, pp. 19–48. Activity, Obesity, and Morbidity,” American Journal
of Health Promotion 18, no. 1 (September/October
18. Peter Calthorpe, The Next American Metropolis: 2003): 47–57.
Ecology, Community, and the American Dream (New
York: Princeton Architectural Press, 1993), p. 17. 32. Jean Eid, Henry G. Overman, Diego Puga, and
Matthew A. Turner, Fat City: Questioning the Re-
19. Dowell Myers and Elizabeth Gearin, “Current lationship Between Urban Sprawl and Obesity (Toronto:
Preferences and Future Demand for Denser Resi- University of Toronto, 2006), p. 1.
dential Environments,” Housing Policy Debate 12,
no. 4 (2001): 635–36. 33. Hall, Cities of Tomorrow, p. 79.
20. John W. Frece, “Lessons from Maryland’s 34. Ewing et al., Growing Cooler, p. iii.
Smart Growth Initiative,” Vermont Journal of En-
vironmental Law 6 (2004–2005), tinyurl.com/8sj28. 35. Making the Connections: A Summary of the
LUTRAQ Project (Portland: 1000 Friends, 1997).
21. 1997 Natural Resources Inventory (Washington:
Natural Resources Conservation Service, 2001), 36. Bent Flyvbjerg, How Optimism Bias and Strategic
tables 1 and 2. Misrepresentation Undermine Implementation (Trond-
heim, Norway: Norges Teknisk-Naturvitenska-
22. “1970–2008 Average Annual Emissions, All pelige Universitet, 2007).
Criteria Pollutants in MS Excel,” Environmental
Protection Agency, 2009, tinyurl.com/nkhgad; 37. Ewing et al., Growing Cooler, p. 10.
Highway Statistics Summary to 1995 (Washington:
Federal Highway Administration, 1996), table VM- 38. Moving Cooler, p. 44.
201; Highway Statistics 2007 (Washington: Federal
Highway Administration, 2008), table VM-2. 39. Moving Cooler, pp. 24, 41.

23. Stacy C. Davis and Susan W. Diegel, Transpor- 40. Calculated by multiplying the 33 percent of
tation Energy Data Book: Edition 28 (Oak Ridge, TN: emissions that come from transportation by the 57
Department of Energy, 2009), table 2.13. percent of transportation emissions that come
from autos and light trucks (see Brown, South-
24. Highway Statistics Summary to 1995, tables MF- worth, and Sarzynski, “Shrinking the Carbon
202 and VM-202. Footprint of Metropolitan America,” p. 8) and the
67 percent of auto and light-truck travel that takes
25. “Light-Duty Automotive Technology and Fuel place in urban areas (see Highway Statistics 2007,
Economy Trends: 1975 through 2008,” Environ- table VM-1).
mental Protection Agency, 2008, p. 7.
41. See, for example, Patrick J. Michaels and Robert
26. Real Estate Research Corporation, The Costs of Balling Jr., Climate of Extremes: Global Warming
Sprawl (Washington: Council on Environmental Science They Don’t Want You to Know (Washington:
Quality, 1973). Cato, 2009).

27. Robert Burchell et al., The Costs of Sprawl 2000 42. Reducing U.S. Greenhouse Gas Emissions: How
(Washington: National Academy Press, 2002), Much at What Cost? (Washington: McKinsey, 2008),
p. 13. pp. 20, 27.

28. Wendell Cox and Joshua Utt, “The Costs of 43. Ewing et al., Growing Cooler, p. 1.

20
44. Reducing U.S. Greenhouse Gas Emissions, p. 21. Moving Cooler Steering Committee, December 11,
2008), p. 19.
45. Ewing et al., Growing Cooler, p. 2.
63. Cambridge Systematics, p. 21.
46. Ibid., p. 3.
64. Cambridge Systematics, pp. 32, 40.
47. Ibid., p. 127.
65. “High Speed Rail and Greenhouse Gas Emis-
48. Ibid., p. 19. sions in the U.S.” Center for Clean Air Policy and
Center for Neighborhood Technology, 2006, p. 9.
49. Arthur C. Nelson, “Leadership in a New Era,”
Journal of the American Planning Association 72, no, 4 66. “Monthly Performance Report for September
(2006): 397. 2008,” Amtrak, 2008, p. C-1, tinyurl.com/njlnhr;
calculated by dividing “contribution per seat
50. Dowell Myers and Elizabeth Gearin, “Current mile” by “contribution per passenger mile.”
Preferences and Future Demand for Denser Resi-
dential Environments,” Housing Policy Debate 12, 67. Moving Cooler, pp. 2–3.
no. 4 (2001): 633–59.
68. Ibid., p. 41.
51. Brown, Southworth, and Sarzynski, “Shrink-
ing the Carbon Footprint of Metropolitan Amer- 69. Randal O’Toole, “Does Rail Transit Save Energy
ica,” p. 9. or Reduce Greenhouse Gas Emissions?” Cato In-
stitute Policy Analysis no. 615, April 14, 2008, pp. 4,
52. Ibid., p. 11. 14.

53. 2008 Buildings Energy Data Book (Pittsburgh: 70. Cambridge Systematics, p. 38.
National Energy Technology Laboratory, 2008),
pp. 2—7. 71. Steven Polzin, “Energy Crisis Solved!” Urban
Transportation Monitor, July 11, 2008, pp. 8–9.
54. Steve Winkelman, Allison Bishins, and Chuck
Kooshian, “Cost-Effective GHG Reductions through 72. Stacy C. Davis and Susan W. Diegel, Transpor-
Smart Growth and Improved Transportation tation Energy Data Book: Edition 28 (Oak Ridge, TN:
Choices,” Center for Clean Air Policy, 2009, pp. v–vi. Department of Energy, 2009), table 2.14.

55. Ibid., p. vi. 73. Moving Cooler, pp. 24, 41.

56. 2006 Metropolitan Transportation Plan (Sacramen- 74. Ibid., p. 44.


to: Sacramento Area Council of Governments,
2006), p. 3. 75. Driving and the Built Environment, p. 2.

57. Winkelman et al., “Cost-Effective GHG Reduc- 76. Ibid., p. 94.


tions,” p. vi.
77. Ibid., p. 96.
58. Randal O’Toole, “Debunking Portland: The
City That Doesn’t Work,” Cato Institute Policy 78. David Brownstone, “Key Relationships Between
Analysis no. 596, July 9, 2007, pp. 8–9. the Built Environment and VMT,” Transportation
Research Board, 2008, p. 7, tinyurl.com/y9mro58.
59. Winkelman et al., “Cost-Effective GHG Reduc-
tions,” p. vi. 79. Ibid., p. 6, tinyurl.com/y85etbs.

60. James Murdock, “Next Stop: Atlantic Station,” 80. Kara Kockelman, Matthew Bomberg, Melissa
Commercial Property News, August 1, 2003, tinyurl. Thompson, and Charlotte Whitehead, “GHG Emis-
com/ydd5kjp. sions Control Options: Opportunities for Conser-
vation,” Transportation Research Board, 2008, pp.
61. Richard Dye and David Merriman, “The Effects 57–58, tinyurl.com/yczl8oc.
of Tax-Increment Financing on Economic Devel-
opment,” Journal of Urban Economics 47, no. 2 81. Michael Bronzini, “Relationships between Land
(2000): 306–28. Use and Freight and Commercial Truck Traffic in
Metropolitan Areas,” Transportation Research
62. Cambridge Systematics, “Updated Assump- Board, 2008, p. 13, tinyurl.com/yaegcpz.
tions and Methodology Used in Moving Cooler
Effectiveness Analysis,” (memorandum to the 82. John Pitkin and Dowell Myers, “U.S. Housing

21
Trends: Generational Changes and the Outlook 99. Sam Adams, “From Here to Portland’s Tomor-
to 2050,” Transportation Research Board, 2008, row” (speech to Portland City Club, July 20, 2007),
p. 4, tinyurl.com/y98hnt9. tinyurl.com/ao42ft.

83. Ibid., pp. 26–27, tinyurl.com/y98hnt9. 100. Robert Nelson, “Privatizing the Neighbor-
hood: A Proposal to Replace Zoning with Private
84. Genevieve Giuliano, Ajay Agarwal, and Chris- Collective Property Rights to Existing Neighbor-
tian Redfearn, “Metropolitan Spatial Trends in hoods,” George Mason Law Review 7, no. 4 (1999):
Employment and Housing,” Transportation Re- 827–80.
search Board, 2008, p. 29, tinyurl.com/yeue8ja.
101. David Hartgen and Gregory Fields, “Gridlock
85. Ewing et al., Growing Cooler, p. 127. and Growth: The Effect of Traffic Congestion on
Regional Economic Performance,” Reason Foun-
86. Moving Cooler, pp. 2–3. dation Policy Summary of Study no. 371, 2009, p.
6, tinyurl.com/ydxxxc6.
87. Ewing et al., Growing Cooler, p. 10. “Current lev-
els” of carbon dioxide outputs are about 6 billion 102. Panorama of Transport (Brussels: European
metric tons per year according to “Total Energy- Commission, 2007), pp. 108–11; National Trans-
Related Carbon Dioxide Emissions by End-Use portation Statistics (Washington: Bureau of Trans-
Sector, and the Electric Power Sector, by Fuel Type, portation Statistics, 2008), table 1-37.
1949–2007,” Energy Information Administration,
2009, tinyurl.com/59rlos. 103. “Estimated Individual Monthly Motor Vehicle
Travel in the United States—2007–2008,” Federal
88. Ewing et al., Growing Cooler, p. 94. Highway Administration, 2009, tinyurl.com/ybad
3xq; passenger miles calculated at 1.6 times vehicle
89. Xinya Cao, Patricia L. Mokhtarian, and Susan miles, “Transit Ridership Report, Second Quarter
L. Handy, “Examining the Impacts of Residential 2008,” American Public Transportation Associ-
Self-Selection on Travel Behavior: Methodologies ation, 2008, tinyurl.com/y9cjn7p; passenger miles
and Empirical Findings,” University of California calculated at 5 times transit trips.
Institute for Transportation Studies, 2008, p. 1.
104. “National Economic Accounts,” Bureau of
90. Brownstone, “Key Relationships,” p. 7, tinyurl. Economic Analysis, 2008, table 2.5.5; Highway Stat-
com/y9mro58. istics 2007, table VM-1.
91. Phil McKenna, “Forget Curbing Urban Sprawl: 105. 2007 National Transit Database (Washington:
Building Denser Cities Would Do Little to Reduce Federal Transit Administration, 2007), “Capital
Carbon Dioxide Emissions, a New NAS Report Use,” “Operating Expenses,” “Fare Revenues,” and
Concludes,” MIT Technology Review, September 3, “Service” spreadsheets.
2009, tinyurl.com/lkbo3c.
106. Randal O’Toole, “The Planning Tax: The Case
92. Moving Cooler, p. 53. against Regional Growth-Management Planning,”
Cato Institute Policy Analysis no. 606, December 6,
93. McKenna, “Forget Curbing Urban Sprawl.” 2007, p. 10.
94. “Transportation Planning,” Oregon Admini- 107. Randal O’Toole, “How Urban Planners Cause
strative Rules 660-12-0035(4)(c). the Housing Bubble,” Cato Institute Policy Anal-
ysis no. 646, October 1, 2009, p. 12.
95. Using Income Criteria to Protect Commercial
Farmland in the State of Oregon (Salem, OR: Depart- 108. Tracey Kaplan and Sue McAllister, “Cost of
ment of Land Conservation and Development, Land Drives Home Prices,” San Jose Mercury News,
1998), p. 2. August 4, 2002.
96. “Zoning Acres by County,” Department of 109. Tom Means, Edward Stringham, and Edward
Land Conservation and Development, 1995. Lopez, “Below-Market Housing Mandates as Tak-
ings: Measuring the Impact,” Independent Insti-
97. Amy Reifenrath, “Road to Bigger, Better Dam- tute Policy Report, November, 2007, p. 1.
ascus Leads to Dead End,” Oregonian, January 16,
2009, tinyurl.com/ahwwfa. 110. Ewing et al., Growing Cooler, p. 8.
98. Dionne Peeples-Salah, “Rezoning for Transit 111. Donald R. Haurin, The Private and Social Bene-
Traps Downtown Homeowners,” Oregonian, Jan- fits of Homeownership (Americus, GA: Habitat for
uary 18, 1996, p. A1. Humanity University, 2003), tinyurl.com/2nnl6t.

22
112. Andrew Oswald, “Theory of Homes and Jobs,” Years of City and Regional Planning at UC–Berkeley: A
preliminary paper, 1997, tinyurl.com/2pfwvv. Celebratory Anthology of Faculty Essays (Berkeley:
Department of City and Regional Planning, 1998).
113. Joel Kotkin, “Opportunity Urbanism: An
Emerging Paradigm for the 21st Century,” Greater 121. Kerri Sullivan, Transportation and Work: Ex-
Houston Partnership, 2007, p. 37, tinyurl.com/25w ploring Car Usage and Employment Outcomes (Cam-
j8f. bridge: Harvard, 2003), tinyurl.com/yonw9f.

114. James Temple, “Exodus of San Francisco’s 122. Steven Raphael and Michael Stoll, “Can
Middle Class,” San Francisco Chronicle, June 22, 2008, Boosting Minority Car-Ownership Rates Narrow
tinyurl.com/5ydpnp; Edward Glaeser, “The Econo- Inter-Racial Employment Gaps?” (Berkeley: Berke-
mic Impact of Restricting Housing Supply,” Rappa- ley Program on Housing and Urban Policy, 2000),
port Institute, 2006, p. 2, tinyurl.com/6zsovh. p. 2, tinyurl.com/2yeuvq.

115. “Urban Renewal History Appendix,” Port- 123. Alan Pisarski, “Cars, Women, and Minorities:
land Development Commission, 2006, pp. 1–5, The Democratization of Mobility in America,”
tinyurl.com/yo2zde. Competitive Enterprise Institute, 1999, p. 1, tiny
url.com/yeno7wr.
116. Pitkin and Myers, “U.S. Housing Trends,” p.
26. 124. Genevieve Giuliano, Hsi-Hwa Hu, and Kyoung
Lee, “The Role of Public Transit in the Mobility of
117. Metropolitan Council, Transportation Policy Low-Income Households,” Metrans Transporta-
Plan (St. Paul: Metropolitan Council, 1996), p. 54. tion Center, 2001, p. ii, tinyurl.com/y9 m255k.

118. “Minutes of the Metro Council Transportation 125. Ohio Kentucky Indiana Regional Council of
Planning Committee Meeting,” Metro (Portland, Governments, OKI 2030 Regional Transportation
Oregon), July 18, 2000, p. 7. Plan (Cincinnati: OKI, 2001), pp. 16–10.

119. Cambridge Systematics, p. 15. 126. Moving Cooler, p. 41.

120. Robert Cervero, “Why Go Anywhere?” in Fifty 127. Ibid., p. 41.

23
STUDIES IN THE POLICY ANALYSIS SERIES

652. Attack of the Utility Monsters: The New Threats to Free Speech by Jason
Kuznicki (November 16, 2009)

651. Fairness 2.0: Media Content Regulation in the 21st Century by Robert
Corn-Revere (November 10, 2009)

650. Yes, Mr President: A Free Market Can Fix Health Care by Michael F.
Cannon (October 21, 2009)

649. Somalia, Redux: A More Hands-Off Approach by David Axe (October 12,
2009)

648. Would a Stricter Fed Policy and Financial Regulation Have Averted the
Financial Crisis? by Jagadeesh Gokhale and Peter Van Doren (October 8, 2009)

647. Why Sustainability Standards for Biofuel Production Make Little


Economic Sense by Harry de Gorter and David R. Just (October 7, 2009)

646. How Urban Planners Caused the Housing Bubble by Randal O’Toole
(October 1, 2009)

645. Vallejo Con Dios: Why Public Sector Unionism Is a Bad Deal for
Taxpayers and Representative Government by Don Bellante, David
Denholm, and Ivan Osorio (September 28, 2009)

644. Getting What You Paid For—Paying For What You Get: Proposals for the
Next Transportation Reauthorization by Randal O’Toole (September 15, 2009)

643. Halfway to Where? Answering the Key Questions of Health Care Reform
by Michael Tanner (September 9, 2009)

642. Fannie Med? Why a “Public Option” Is Hazardous to Your Health by


Michael F. Cannon (July 27, 2009)

641. The Poverty of Preschool Promises: Saving Children and Money with the
Early Education Tax Credit by Adam B. Schaeffer (August 3, 2009)

640. Thinking Clearly about Economic Inequality by Will Wilkinson (July 14,
2009)

You might also like