You are on page 1of 12

Macro

Global Economics
abc
Global Research

China’s Dilemma China will approach renminbi reform


step by step...
Options for the renminbi
...but will the steps be small or, instead,
giant leaps?

We assess the options open to the


Chinese authorities and their
implications for the global economy

Which option is best?


The speculation may, eventually, amount to nothing at all
but, for the time being, markets are obsessed with what
China may – or may not – do about its exchange rate regime.

This piece is an update of the arguments presented in “To Be


a Rock and Not to Roll” (January 2005). Our assumption
remains that the Chinese authorities will focus primarily on
domestic financial reform with only limited changes likely to
the exchange rate regime in the coming months.

Nevertheless, given the ongoing speculation – and the


heightened pressure stemming from the US Treasury and
Congress - we take a quick look at the alternative exchange
rate arrangements on offer, both in the form of one-off
changes in value against the dollar and more strategic
changes in currency regime.

Demands for a one-off revaluation against the dollar are


likely to fall on deaf ears in Beijing. A small revaluation
20 May 2005 would achieve very little yet threaten greater ongoing
Stephen King instability. A large revaluation would be too much a victory
Economist for the Americans and probably wouldn’t do the trick longer
+44 20 7991 6700 stephen.king@hsbcib.com
term: declines in Chinese wages and prices would imply a
Janet Henry
rapid restoration of China’s competitive advantage.
Economist
+44 20 7991 6711 janet.henry@hsbcib.com
More plausible options include a crawling peg and a
Qu Hongbin currency basket. In both cases, China wouldn’t have to
Economist
+852 2822 2025 hongbinqu@hsbc.com.hk suffer a sudden exchange rate shock, in both cases the
regime would be relatively transparent and in both cases the
Richard Yetsenga
Currency Strategist Chinese could argue that more flexibility had been
+852 2822 1933 richard.yetsenga@hsbc.com.hk introduced into the regime. Neither option, though, would
necessarily require a large adjustment against the dollar or,
Disclaimer and Disclosures indeed, against any other currency.
This report must be read with the
disclaimer, disclosures and analyst
certifications on p11 that form part of it
Macro
Global Economics abc
20 May 2005

China’s Dilemma
Any renminbi reform is likely to be limited...
...and US hopes of a large revaluation against the dollar are
unfounded.
Small steps, not giant leaps, will remain the Chinese leadership’s
preferred approach

Speculation and truth revaluation will be going from 1.26 to 6.03


percent in a span of one month and one year......”.
In “To Be a Rock and not to Roll”, we argued that
On the very same day, the Deputy Governor of
many of the arguments used in favour of a
the People’s Bank of China (PBOC), Wu Xiaoling
renminbi revaluation did not stand up to close
in an interview with the Nikkei said that while
scrutiny. In particular, a renminbi appreciation
China is “technically” ready for yuan reforms
was unlikely to make much difference to the
“China’s reform is not proceeding under external
economic imbalances that exist around the world,
pressure. If expectations that the yuan will
notably the growing size of the US current
appreciate grows and a large amount of foreign
account deficit. We also argued that some of the
capital flows into the country, it will be difficult to
proposed changes to the current regime – a peg
push forward the macro-economic policies”.
against the dollar – would pose risks for China,
threatening economic instability. Given these seemingly rather different views, it’s
hardly surprising that speculation refuses to die
Regardless of our views, however, speculation
down particularly given that, if China were to
continues to mount that a change in China’s
make a change now, it would be doing so from a
renminbi policy is imminent, despite the
position of strength not often afforded to a rapidly
occasional – and sometime forceful – claims to
expanding emerging market: the currency is under
the contrary from Chinese officials. In part, this is
upward pressure and the trade surplus has been
because stories emerging from China have, from
rising rapidly in recent months. Ultimately,
time to time, been contradictory. On 10 May, a
though, all we know at this stage is that China has
story posted on the English language website of
agreed to “push forward market-oriented
China’s People’s Daily – now discredited as an
exchange rate system reform. Our objective is
inaccurate translation but enough to create
very clear. But we have our own plan for the
headlines around the world - claimed that “.the
sequence and order of the reform. We will
appreciation of the people's currency as wished
implement the reform step-by-step according to
for by the international financial market will be
China’s own conditions” (Zhou Xiaochun,
announced to revaluate or expand the margins of
Governor of the PBOC, speaking in April).
its exchange rate and the estimation of the

2
Macro
Global Economics abc
20 May 2005

Reforms are certainly on the way, but the 1. RMB has been stable since early 1990s

sequencing of reforms – and the position of Chinese Renminbi to US$


10 10
exchange rate policy within those reforms – is still
a matter for considerable debate. 8 8

6 6
This short paper reviews the possible currency
regime options open to China, and highlights their 4 4
implications both for China itself and for other 2 2
economies. It’s worth noting at the outset that
0 0
any decision made by the Chinese carries
57 61 65 69 73 77 81 85 89 93 97 01 05
economic risk but that the decision will ultimately
be based not only on economic factors but on Source: Thomson Financial Datastream

political factors as well. Chinese Premier Wen


Jiabao said on 16 May in comments to a US
Option 1: Leave the renminbi
Chamber of Commerce delegation, “Currently,
there are some problems in Sino-US trade. The
unchanged
problems should not be politicised. Reform of the Given the increased hostility both from the US
renminbi’s exchange rate is a matter of China’s Congress and Administration, this would hardly
own sovereignty. Any pressure or media play-up be welcome in Washington. Nevertheless, as we
will not help solve problems”. argued in To Be a Rock and Not To Roll, an
unchanged policy has substantial attractions for
Despite these comments, however, the pressure
China. Transparency is maintained. Intervention,
continues to mount. In the US Treasury’s latest
if needed, has limited side-effects domestically
“Report to Congress on International Economic
(China could intervene indefinitely: the Chinese
and Exchange Rate Policies” (May 2005),
issue domestic bonds to mop up excess liquidity
“current Chinese policies are highly
associated with rising foreign exchange reserves
distortionary....if current trends continue without
but yields on those bonds are lower than yields on
substantial alteration, China’s policies will likely
US Treasuries, implying no negative carry). And
meet the...requirements for designation [as a
intervention is working: money supply growth has
currency manipulator]”. The report went on to
slowed significantly over the last twelve months
say that “it is widely accepted that China is now
despite the rapid increase in foreign exchange
ready and should move without delay in a manner
reserves.
and magnitude that is sufficiently reflective of
underlying market conditions”. Although John
Snow, the US Treasury Secretary, indicated after
the report’s release that there was no need for an
immediate free float, indications from the
Treasury were that a substantial move was
required and that a 5% revaluation would not
satisfy US interests nor quell rising protectionist
pressures in Congress. As yet, then, there appears
to be no meeting of minds between China and the
US.

3
Macro
Global Economics abc
20 May 2005

2. Money supply growth slowing despite rising FX reserves would become cheaper and cheaper as Chinese
% Yr % Yr nominal wages rose relative to US nominal
25 25 wages).
20 20 4 Second, rather than introducing flexibility into
15 15 either the nominal or the real exchange rate,
China could use fiscal levers to change the
10 10
relative pricing structure of exports: higher
5 5 taxes or the withdrawal of subsidies would
99 00 01 02 03 04 05 work in much the same way as an appreciation
M1 M2
of the nominal exchange rate but would be
Source: Thomson Financial Datastream directly controlled by the Chinese
administration. This approach would have
There is also huge uncertainty about the immediate effects but, at the same time, has
renminbi’s fair value. Most calculations - which two key disadvantages. Any change in tax
point to the need for renminbi appreciation - are arrangements might be a tacit admission that
based on trade flows alone. Yet, were the capital the exchange rate was, indeed, undervalued.
account to be fully liberalised, the weak domestic And manipulating fiscal policy, in itself, cannot
banking system could lead to a significant really be regarded as a market-led reform
depreciation of the renminbi. In 2004, for unless there is a general reduction in tax
example, the IMF was forced to conclude that it distortions.
was difficult to tell where the renminbi would end
up were it to be floated (see “China’s Integration 4 Third, China might rebalance its capital
into the World Economy: prospects and account position, placing constraints on capital
challenges”.) It is, therefore, difficult to come up inflows yet, at the same time, encouraging
with a convincing assessment of where the more capital outflows. Current regulations
renminbi should be if there were to be a shift in require exporters and foreign investors to
the parity. surrender at least 70% of their foreign currency
earnings and investment to clearing banks,
One of three possible reforms might be needed to while banks have to sell most of their foreign
continue fixed currency policy against the dollar. currency receipts on the foreign exchange
4 First, China would need to find another market. Yet the demand for foreign currency
mechanism to secure appreciation of the real (except imports) remains depressed due to the
exchange rate over the medium term (the real rigid control over overseas investment, the
exchange rate, in its simplest form, takes into foreign currency holdings of corporations
account movements in both the nominal (including banks) and purchases of foreign
exchange rate and relative inflation rates). The currency by individuals. Rebalancing the
most obvious thing to do would be to announce capital account would reduce the need for
publicly that China’s inflation rate will be continuous intervention to prevent renminbi
higher over the medium term than the US appreciation.
inflation rate, implying a continuous terms of Implications: A fixed renminbi, with reform,
trade improvement for Chinese consumers (in would be easy for China to absorb but would do
their eyes, US goods, priced in renminbi, nothing to allay US protectionist pressures.

4
Macro
Global Economics abc
20 May 2005

Whether the US would proceed with import tariffs dollar as a result of the Smithsonian agreement in
is, of course, another matter altogether, but this December 1971, itself a response to President
option would certainly increase political tension, Nixon’s decision to impose import tariffs on other
even if the economic attractions for China seem Bretton Woods members in August of that year.
relatively high. Moreover, were the dollar to The appreciation, though, proved to be a
weaken further against other currrencies, the speculator’s dream – and a policymaker’s
renminbi’s own competitive position would nightmare. The adjustment was a clear
improve, perhaps increasing trade tensions with compromise between those countries that wanted
other parts of the world. no change and the Americans who wanted a much
more substantial move. More moves were
Option 2: Allow a small expected and, as a result, speculators began to
revaluation of the order of take advantage of a system that was no longer
completely fixed but, instead, unpredictably
3-6% against the dollar
adjustable. By 1973, the system had completely
This is the event implied by pricing on non- collapsed.
deliverable forwards, which anticipate a 6% rise
in the renminbi against the dollar over the next Implications: In current circumstances, it is
twelve months. It could take the form of either a difficult to believe that there would be any serious
one-off revaluation or a widening of the band to benefit to either the Chinese or to the Americans.
3%-6% from 0.03% currently. A move of this The move would be no more than cosmetic,
scale might contain some political symbolism but, designed to buy time, but could have the
economically, it would be, at best, largely unfortunate consequence of creating even more
irrelevant and, at worst, seriously destabilising. speculative pressures than exist today. Small
Note that China accounts for around 10% of all adjustments generally don’t work when there is
US trade so a 6% renminbi appreciation would, on great deal of speculative pressure. In Indonesia in
its own, imply a decline in the dollar’s trade- 1997/98, for example, the authorities initially
weighted exchange rate of a mere 0.6%. Even if attempted to slow the pace of the currency’s
all other Asian countries were to follow suit – depreciation by widening the intervention band
and, given Japan’s economic weakness, this may from 8% to 12% but speculative pressure
be an extreme assumption – the dollar would only intensified and the exchange rate immediately fell
fall in trade-weighted terms by around 2½%. to its new lower boundary. The currency changed
Moves of this scale will have no significant to a float in a matter of weeks. Similarly, in
impact on external imbalances. In particular, the Mexico in December 19994 the initial 15%
US current account deficit would continue to devaluation did little to curb speculative selling
widen. Protectionist pressures might be put on and the currency was floated two days later. It
hold for a while but would likely return at some seems unlikely that a revaluation of 3%–6%
point over the next couple of years. would quell the current speculative pressure on
the renminbi.
Perhaps the bigger issue is whether a move of this
size would mark the end of any adjustment. The
breakdown of the Bretton Woods exchange rate
system in the early-1970s was initially associated
with a small realignment of currencies against the

5
Macro
Global Economics abc
20 May 2005

Option 3: Allow a large leading to distortions to Hong Kong monetary


appreciation of around 20% policy that could destabilise the economy there.
against the dollar Implications: This kind of revaluation would
The least plausible option. A large appreciation almost certainly be associated with an
might keep US politicians happy for a while but it appreciation of the managed floating exchange
wouldn’t do much for the Chinese economy. rates in Asia (particularly the yen) although
Falling import prices, the result of a large probably not all of the fixed rates (Malaysia
appreciation, would boost domestically based would probably move but others wouldn’t). A
investment in exchange for lower exports and, large one-off revaluation would probably also
therefore, might lead to an even bigger domestic imply a less marked appreciation of the euro
imbalance than China already has (for a parallel, against the dollar than would otherwise have been
think of Japan’s experience in the late-1980s the case. As for the emerging European
where substantial yen appreciation was currencies, a renminbi revaluation would not have
accompanied by severe domestic overheating). any significant direct implications; movements in
Lower demand for Chinese exports might, in turn, euro/dollar would remain the major influence.
prompt wage and price cuts which would quickly Even if there is no appreciation vis-à-vis the
restore the real exchange rate to earlier, more dollar outside China it seems unlikely that even a
competitive, levels. revaluation of this magnitude would narrow
China’s huge labour cost advantage significantly
For state-owned companies, many of whom
over the medium term. Moreover, while a 20%
operate on razor-thin margins given their
revaluation would satisfy the US initially, it
employment-maximising rather than profit-
would not fulfil either US demands, or China’s
maximising approach, even a short-term loss of
stated intention, to move towards increased
competitiveness would be likely to reduce profits
“flexibility” of the exchange rate at some stage.
or increase losses. This would have negative
implications for the state-owned banks –
particularly their non-performing loans - and Option 4: A currency basket
government finances. target
China’s inflation would probably fall, although One of the more plausible scenarios. Pegging the
the government could take the opportunity to exchange rate to a number of different currencies,
accelerate the deregulation of prices of oil and rather than just the US$ basically amounts to a
other products, thereby allowing some of the so- stabilisation of the effective exchange rate which
called “hidden” inflation to come through and would insulate the currency from external
reducing some of the effective subsidy which has exchange rate shocks. Linking the exchange rate
encouraged over-investment in recent years. to a basket of currencies may or may not be
associated with a one-off
There would also be difficulties for Hong Kong appreciation/depreciation of the effective rate.
SAR. A rise of 20% in the renminbi would take it
above the HK$7.75 upside limit set by the Hong One key difficulty is determining the optimal
Kong Monetary Authority and could encourage weights for such a basket. Should it be based on
speculation on the Hong Kong dollar as well, different countries’ share of China’s exports? Or
its imports? Or both? Should it also incorporate
currencies from those countries with which it does

6
Macro
Global Economics abc
20 May 2005

not have a large amount of direct trade but with Implications: A currency basket would provide a
which it competes? Should the basket make more economically rounded and relevant target
allowances for commodities priced in dollars, or for the Chinese authorities to aim at. However, it
for the sources of capital flows? And what of the would introduce uncertainty into all bilateral
rapid change in China’s trade shares from one currency arrangements whereas at least there is
year to the next? currently certainty with regard to the dollar. Such
a regime would presumably only satisfy the US
Table 3 lists China’s major trading partners based
authorities as long as the dollar is perpetually
on total trade shares. If one assumes that any shift
falling; if the euro and/or yen weakened in value
to a currency basket in China is not accompanied
this would obviously imply a renminbi
by a regime change in other Asian exchange rates
depreciation vis-à-vis the US dollar.
currently pegged or managed against the US
dollar, these weights would basically imply that
the US dollar would have about a 55% weight in Option 5: A crawling peg
the currency basket, the euro 20% and the yen A crawling peg allows the government or central
15%. bank to adjust the value of the exchange rate peg
periodically, typically based on past inflation
3. China’s main trading partners: share of total main partner
trade (2004) differentials vis-à-vis major trading partners. In
Country/region Share (numbers add to 100) countries where this regime has been used in the
EU 21.5 past (e.g. Israel, Poland and Hungary) it has
US 17.2
Japan 17.0 typically been to engineer a gradual depreciation
Hong Kong 11.5 of the exchange rate.
Korea 9.1
Taiwan 8.0
4. A crawling peg appreciating by 6% per annum
Singapore 2.7
Malaysia 2.7
Russia 2.2 8.5 8.5
Australia 2.1
Thailand 1.8
Renminbi/US$
Renminbi/US$

Canada 1.6 8.0 8.0


Indonesia 1.4
Philippines 1.4
7.5 7.5
Source: Thomson Financial Datastream

7.0 7.0
Like the crawling peg (see below), a currency
basket has been used by some countries as part of 6.5 6.5

a transition from a peg to a floating regime. From t-2 t-1 t t+1 t+2 t+3

1973 to 1985 Singapore pegged the Singapore Source: Thomson Financial Datastream
dollar against a fixed and undisclosed trade-
weighted basket of currencies. Capital controls In the case of China this would presumably take
were fully abolished in 1978 and since 1985 the the form of allowing the renminbi to appreciate
currency has been allowed to float. But it is against the dollar at a pre-announced rate (see
monitored by the Monetary Authority of chart 4 for an illustrative example).
Singapore against a currency basket (known to be
A crawling peg has often been used in countries
based on exports, imports and third country
as part of the transition from a fixed peg to a
competitiveness) with the aim of maintaining a
floating regime and to that extent would probably
low and stable domestic inflation rate.

7
Macro
Global Economics abc
20 May 2005

be more likely to appease the Americans than just peg. Would it end the speculation pressure?
a one-off 3-6% revaluation. Not only would it be Probably not. Obviously much would depend on
a commitment to a more medium-term adjustment the rate at which the crawling peg moved but
of the exchange rate, rather than just a one-off assuming it is a fairly modest annual appreciation,
revaluation, it would probably also be viewed as many of the arguments set out in “Option 2: Allow
the start of a shift to much greater exchange rate a small revaluation of the order of 3-6% against
flexibility. the dollar” apply here also. Unless the US
welcomed the change as the appropriate stepping
5. A peg within symmetric crawling bands
stone to a complete liberalisation of the Chinese
8.5 8.5 foreign exchange market, speculation might
Renminbi/US$

8.0 8.0 persist about shifts in the pace of managed


Renminbi/US$

7.5 7.5
appreciation.

7.0 7.0
Option 6: A managed float
6.5 6.5
A managed float would have some similarities
6.0 6.0
with both currency basket and crawling peg
t-2 t-1 t t+1 t+2 t+3
Pegged rate 2% pa 4% pa arrangements. There would be no pre-announced
Source: Thomson Financial Datastream
trading ranges, nor pre-announced targets for
levels of the exchange rate in a year or two’s time.
A variation on the crawling peg regime would be Nor would there have to be an announced
a pegged exchange rate within crawling bands. currency basket target. Markets, though, would
Bands could be either symmetric around a be able to observe the performance of a managed
crawling central peg (which strengthens at a pre- float over time and learn something about the
announced rate) or widen gradually within authorities’ reaction function. After a while, it
asymmetric upper and lower bands allowing for would be possible for markets to “second-guess”
different degrees of appreciation (in which case how the authorities would react to different
there would probably not be a pre-announced shocks. This “learning process” would, over time,
central rate). imply that markets would look upon a managed
float in a similar – although slightly less certain –
6. Crawling peg within asymmetric bands
way to either a currency basket or crawling peg.
8.5 8.5 The main advantage would be the absence of any
formal target for speculators to attack. The
Renminbi/US$

8.0 8.0
disadvantage, at least at this stage, might be the
Renminbi/US$

7.5 7.5
lack of a transparent monetary target in the
7.0 7.0
transition to a more market-based financial
6.5 6.5 system, fostering uncertainty along the way.
6.0 6.0
Implications: A managed float has proved popular
t-2 t-1 t t+1 t+2 t+3
with a number of Asian countries – India, Japan
Current rate 2% pa 8% pa
and Taiwan spring to mind – but it might be a step
Source: Thomson Financial Datastream
too far for China given limited domestic reforms.
Implications: A crawling peg basically imposes
A managed float might be the eventual outcome
the same constraints on monetary policy as a fixed

8
Macro
Global Economics abc
20 May 2005

after years of reform but we suspect that currency undervalued”. Others disagree. The Institute for
basket or crawling peg arrangements would be International Economics in Washington used two
more credible short-term stepping stones. different approaches to argue that the renminbi is
15-30% undervalued, but admitted that these
Option 7: A freely-floating calculations took no account of the likely capital
exchange rate outflow that might be associated with
liberalisation of the capital account.
Following the Asian and Russian crises of the
late-1990s a new consensus emerged that either Implications: The surge in capital inflows that
“firmly fixed” or “fully floating” exchange rates would be associated with such an appreciation
were the only workable options as pegged could cause serious disruptions to China’s
exchange rates of the adjustable sort were no financial system and real economy, though the
longer viable because of their vulnerability to Chinese authorities could impose credit controls
speculative attacks. So, to that extent, a free float on banks to prevent a lending surge. The
would be the obvious alternative to the current implications of the initial appreciation would be
regime. However a free float would require an an exaggerated version of those described under
alternative credible domestic monetary “Option 3: Allow a large appreciation of around
arrangement such as an inflation target or money 20% against the dollar”. Such a move would
supply target which clearly does not yet exist in result in a rise in US treasury yields, particularly
China. Moreover, given the limited degree of if associated with a switch within the rest of the
domestic financial market reform, the credibility Asian region towards free floats or pegs other
of any such domestic nominal target would be in than the dollar. If the move reflected in part the
serious doubt: the link between interest rates and US dollar starting to lose its reserve currency
money supply is poor, primarily because status it could also trigger a switch by commodity
monetary policy is still conducted through producers to price their commodities in euros
quantitative restrictions on credit expansion rather rather than dollars and lead to a generally higher
than price. risk premium on all US assets.

A free float would also have to be associated with And while the initial impact of a free float could
full capital account liberalisation. Alan Greenspan be negative for China, a subsequent reversal of
has pointed out on several occasions that the capital flows could be equally disruptive, leaving
existence of capital controls means no one really this option as the most risky and least likely for
knows what would happen to the RMB in the the Chinese authorities to consider.
event of a freely floating Chinese exchange rate.
However, it seems plausible under current market Option 8: Asian currency unit
conditions that the renminbi would appreciate
A much longer term option, which would
sharply, overshooting – at least temporarily –
probably only happen after much of the region has
most measures of fair value. Fair value for the
shifted to more flexible exchange rate regimes,
renminbi is itself a moot point with estimates
would be the re-pegging to either a common
varying widely. An IMF report (Article IV
regional currency basket or a synthetic new
Consultation with the People’s Republic of China)
currency (Asian Currency Unit). This would have
published in November 2003 found "no clear
the advantage of reducing concerns about
evidence that the currency is substantially
competitive devaluations and avoid the current

9
Macro
Global Economics abc
20 May 2005

situation whereby other Asian economies, were to be a shift in the regime, the shift would
including Japan, use China’s lack of currency more likely be one of mechanism rather than
flexibility to justify their own currency magnitude. Given the huge uncertainties about
intervention. It also makes sense given the the renminbi’s fair value against the dollar and
increased importance of intra-regional trade. other currencies, a one-off revaluation doesn’t
However, there would also be political difficulties look likely. Instead, any change is more likely to
in its implementation, particularly if it were to focus on band widening, a crawling peg, a
involve the formation of some kind of Asian currency basket target or some combination of all
central bank. three. (It is worth noting that Chile used all of
these at various stages in the 1980s and 1990s to
Implications: Still a long way off and a lot would
achieve both exchange rate appreciation and
have to change politically to make it happen.
depreciation.) Changes of this kind would
Would present challenge to the dollar and the euro
certainly introduce greater flexibility into China’s
as a reserve currency.
foreign exchange market but, on their own, would
provide no guarantee of any sizeable change in
Conclusions China’s competitive position vis-à-vis the United
Conditions for a change in currency regime are States.
certainly more helpful than they were a year ago.
As a result, external imbalances would be only
The balance of payments position is strong – an
modestly affected by any changes in Chinese
auspicious backdrop – and there have been a
exchange rate arrangements. As we have
number of changes that have improved the
consistently argued, for any meaningful reduction
institutional structure of the domestic foreign
in the US current account deficit something has to
exchange market:
change with regard to relative demand growth in
4 Eliminating regulations that stifle trading the US and elsewhere in the world. Any long-term
activity, allowing exporters to retain more solution to the current account deficit would have
foreign exchange earnings. to involve a sustained period of US fiscal
consolidation and a commitment to greater
4 Allowing more flexibility in the cash
structural reform in the eurozone. Greater
management of foreign companies operating in
currency flexibility in Asia may help modestly but
China.
would have to be accompanied by a policy-shift
4 Encouraging companies to make long-term towards domestic-demand-boosting policies and a
investments in foreign markets. willingness suddenly to run massively-reduced
current account surpluses if not deficits. In the
4 Permitting local residents to buy foreign
meantime, protectionist pressures seem unlikely
currency for both foreign education and
to die down.
holidays.

Hopes, though, of a revolutionary shift are


overdone. Further reforms could come without
any shift in the currency regime: a higher inflation
target, changes in the restrictions on capital
inflows and outflows, or changes in the fiscal
treatment of imports and exports. And if there

10
Macro
Global Economics abc
20 May 2005

Disclaimer
The research analyst(s) who prepared this report certifies(y) that the views expressed herein accurately reflect the research analyst’s(s’) personal views about
the subject security(ies) and issuer(s) and that no part of his/her/their compensation was, is or will be directly or indirectly related to the specific
recommendation(s) or views contained in this research report.
*in this publication, HSBC Group offices are indicated by the following codes: HSBC Bank plc
‘AU’ HSBC Bank plc – Sydney Branch and HSBC Bank Australia Limited; ‘UK’ HSBC Bank plc in London 8 Canada Square, London
in the United Kingdom; ‘DE’ HSBC Trinkaus & Burkhardt KgaA in Dusseldorf, Germany; ‘FR’ HSBC CCF E14 5HQ, United Kingdom
Social SA in Paris, France; ‘HK’ The Hongkong and Shanghai Banking Corporation Limited, in Hong Kong Telephone: +44 20 7991 8888
SAR in China; ‘JP’ HSBC Securities (Japan) Limited in Tokyo, Japan; ‘US’ HSBC Securities (USA) Inc., in Fax: +44 20 7992 4880
New York, USA; 'CA' HSBC Bank Canada. (May 2004) Website: www.research.hsbc.com
Website: www.markets.hsbc.com
This document is issued in the United Kingdom by HSBC Bank plc, which is a member of the London Stock Exchange, and in Australia by HSBC Bank plc –
Sydney Branch (ABN 98 067 329 015) and HSBC Bank Australia Limited (ABN 48 006 434 162) for the general information of its “wholesale” customers (as
defined in the Corporations Act 2001). It makes no representations that the products or services mentioned in this document are available to persons in Australia
or are necessarily suitable for any particular person or appropriate in accordance with local law. No consideration has been given to the particular investment
objectives, financial situation or particular needs of any recipient. The document is distributed in Hong Kong by The Hongkong and Shanghai Banking
Corporation Limited and in Japan by HSBC Securities (Japan) Limited.
Each of the companies listed above (the “Participating Companies”) is a member of the HSBC Group of Companies, any member of which may trade for its
own account as Principal, may have underwritten an issue within the last 36 months or, together with its Directors, officers and employees, may have a long
or short position in securities or instruments or in any related instrument mentioned in the document. Brokerage or fees may be earned by the Participating
Companies or persons associated with them in respect of any business transacted by them in all or any of the securities or instruments referred to in this
document.
The information in this document is derived from sources the Participating Companies believe to be reliable but which have not been independently verified.
The Participating Companies make no guarantee of its accuracy and completeness and are not responsible for errors of transmission of factual or analytical
data, nor shall the Participating Companies be liable for damages arising out of any person’s reliance upon this information. All charts and graphs are from
publicly available sources or proprietary data. The opinions in this document constitute the present judgement of the Participating Companies, which is
subject to change without notice.
This document is neither an offer to sell, purchase or subscribe for any investment nor a solicitation of such an offer. This document is intended for
distribution in the United States solely to “major US institutional investors” as defined in Rule 15a-6 of the US Securities Exchange Act of 1934 and may not
be furnished to any other person in the United States. Each major US institutional investor that receives this document by such act agrees that it shall not
distribute or provide a copy of the document to any other person. Such recipient should note that any transactions effected on their behalf will be undertaken
through HSBC Securities (USA) Inc. in the United States. Note, however, that HSBC Securities (USA) Inc. is not distributing this report, has not contributed
to or participated in its preparation, and does not take responsibility for its contents. Among other things, this means that the legends and other disclosures set
forth in this report do not conform to the rules of the regulatory and self-regulatory organizations to which HSBC Securities (USA) Inc. is subject. The
document is intended to be distributed in its entirety. Unless governing law permits otherwise, you must contact a HSBC Group member in your home
jurisdiction if you wish to use HSBC Group services in effecting a transaction in any investment mentioned in this document. HSBC Bank plc is registered in
England No 14259, is authorised and regulated by the Financial Services Authority and is a member of the London Stock Exchange.
© Copyright. HSBC Bank plc 2005, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted,
on any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise, without the prior written permission of HSBC Bank plc. (March
2005) MITA (P) 105/10/2004

280316

11
abc

Global Economics Team


Global Global Emerging Markets
Stephen King Philip Poole
Global Sector Head +44 20 7991 5237 philip.poole@hsbcib.com
+44 20 7991 6700 stephen.king@hsbcib.com
Asia
Janet Henry Arup Raha
+44 20 7991 6711 janet.henry@hsbcib.com +852 2822 4870 arupraha@hsbc.com.hk
Europe George Leung
+852 2822 4871 georgeleung@hsbc.com.hk
Gwyn Hacche
+44 20 7991 6707 gwyn.hacche@hsbcib.com Qu Hongbin
+852 2822 2025 hongbinqu@hsbc.com.hk
Robert Prior-Wandesforde
+44 20 7991 6708 robert.prior-wandesforde@hsbcib.com Arthur Woo
+852 2822 2096 arthurwoo@hsbc.com.hk
United Kingdom
John Butler Vasan Shridharan
+44 20 7991 6718 john.butler@hsbcib.com +65 6239 0803 vasanshridharan@hsbc.com.sg
Vinay Patel
United States
+91 22 2268 1245 vinaypatel@hsbc.co.in
Ian Morris
Emerging Europe, Middle East & Africa
+1 212 525 3115 ian.morris@us.hsbc.com
David Lubin
Ryan Wang +44 20 7991 5641 david.p.lubin@hsbcib.com
+1 212 525 3181 ryan.wang@us.hsbc.com
Arthur Kamp
Japan +27 11 481 4365 arthur.kamp@za.hsbc.com

Peter Morgan Ahmet AkarlÖ


+81 3 5203 3802 peter.morgan@hsbc.co.jp +90 212 366 1625 ahmetakarli@hsbc.com.tr
Latin America
Paulo Vieira da Cunha
+1 212 525 5741 paulo.vieiradacunha@us.hsbc.com
Benito Berber
+1 212 525 3124 benito.berber@us.hsbc.com
Javier Finkman
+54 11 4344 8144 javier.finkman@hsbc.com.ar
Alexandre Bassoli
+55 11 3371 8304 alexandre.bassoli@hsbc.com.br
Jonathan Heath
+52 55 5721 2176 jonathan.heath@hsbc.com.mx

You might also like