You are on page 1of 11

See

discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/222557467

Simplifying Complexity: a Review of


Complexity Theory

Article in Geoforum August 2001


DOI: 10.1016/S0016-7185(00)00035-X

CITATIONS READS

379 2,122

1 author:

Steven Manson
University of Minnesota Twin Cities
100 PUBLICATIONS 3,349 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Big data of human-environment systems View project

Southern Yucatan Peninsular Research Project View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Steven Manson on 16 March 2017.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file. All in-text references underlined in blue are added to the original document
and are linked to publications on ResearchGate, letting you access and read them immediately.
Geoforum 32 (2001) 405414
www.elsevier.com/locate/geoforum

Simplifying complexity: a review of complexity theory


Steven M. Manson
Graduate School of Geography, Clark University, 950 Main Street, Worcester, MA 01610-1477, USA
Received 5 August 1999; in revised form 7 September 2000

Abstract
Complexity theory has captured the attention of the scientic community to the extent where its proponents tout it as a dominant
scientic trend. Geographers, and environmental, human, and regional planners have applied complexity theory to topics ranging
from cultural transmission and economic growth to the braiding of rivers. While such a wide array of applications is heartening
because it speaks to the utility of complexity theory, it is necessary to move beyond the hyperbole and critically examine the nature
of complexity research. The author therefore provides an overview of the evolution of complexity research, establishes a preliminary
typology of complexity approaches with their advantages and drawbacks, and identies areas of further research. 2001 Elsevier
Science Ltd. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Complexity theory; Chaos; Self-organization; Emergence

1. Introduction research is hard to discover due to the large degree to


which complexity ideas are traded across disciplinary
``Complexity theory is destined to be the dominant boundaries. Thrift (1999), for instance, examines what
scientic trend of the 1990's . . . This revolutionary complexity theory means to, and traces interactions
technique can explain any kind of complex system among, managerial science, the social and natural
multinational corporations, or mass extinctions, or sciences, and new age philosophy. There is also a
ecosystems such as rainforests, or human consciousness. propensity for disciplines to borrow techniques from
All are built on the same few rules.'' (Lewin, 1992: back other disciplines or to speculate naively on subjects
cover). Whether over-exuberance or merely aggressive typically seen as outside their purview (Horgan, 1995;
advertising copy, this bold pronouncement has yet to be Lo Presti, 1996). In either case, exciting academic
fullled. Growing acceptance of complexity is evidenced cross-fertilization occurs at the expense of potentially
by a recent section on complex systems in the journal false leads.
Science (1999) and the increasing amount of complexity In sum, any denition of complexity is beholden to the
research. This interest is countered by concern that perspective brought to bear upon it. While it is possible,
complexity is an over-hyped fad (Sarder and Ravetz, therefore, to examine complexity on a discipline-by-dis-
1994). Does complexity merit the title of a ``dominant cipline basis, breaking complexity research into three
scientic trend'' or are ill-advised scientists rushing to major divisions aords a more coherent understanding of
capitalize on its cachet? What value does complexity complexity theory. ``Algorithmic complexity'', in the
theory hold for geographic research? form of mathematical complexity theory and information
Advocates of complexity theory see it as a means of theory, contends that the complexity of a system lies in
simplifying seemingly complex systems. The actual the diculty faced in describing system characteristics.
practice of complexity theory, however, is anything but ``Deterministic complexity'' deals with chaos theory and
simple in that there is no one identiable complexity catastrophe theory, which posit that the interaction of
theory. Instead, a number of theories concerned with two or three key variables can create largely stable sys-
complex systems gather under the general banner of tems prone to sudden discontinuities. ``Aggregate com-
complexity research. The exact nature of complexity plexity'' concerns how individual elements work in
concert to create systems with complex behavior.
Why have these three divisions if there is an identi-
E-mail address: smanson@clarku.edu (S.M. Manson). able body of complexity theory? The simplest answer is

0016-7185/01/$ - see front matter 2001 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved.
PII: S 0 0 1 6 - 7 1 8 5 ( 0 0 ) 0 0 0 3 5 - X
406 S.M. Manson / Geoforum 32 (2001) 405414

that there are separate kinds of complexity that have plexity research contends that systems have emergent or
dierent and sometimes conicting assumptions and synergistic characteristics that cannot be understood
conclusions. This said, algorithmic, deterministic, and without reference to sub-component relationships. Of
aggregate complexity share more than just the ``com- course, this idea can be traced back to Aristotle, so it is
plexity'' label. To a certain extent, they share the same important to note that complexity research is also con-
historical antecedents, as explored below. In disciplinary cerned with how systems change and evolve over time
terms, researchers often apply dierent kinds of com- due to interaction of their constituent parts.
plexity to a single problem with the understanding that
these approaches are complementary. Similarly, given
that all three kinds of complexity are interested in the 2. Algorithmic complexity
often mathematically intractable aspects of systems,
they regularly rely on computational settings of non- Algorithmic complexity theory makes two relatively
linear mathematics and software simulation. Most im- ancillary contributions to complexity theory overall.
portantly, all three kinds of complexity are concerned One measure of algorithmic complexity calculates the
with how the nature of a system may be characterized eort required to solve a mathematical problem. In
with reference to its constituent parts in a non-reduc- some cases, a problem is so complex or specied in such
tionist manner. a way that it is unsolvable. Spatial statistics and geo-
Taken together, these three kinds of complexity re- graphic information science face this kind of complexity.
search are a recent body of work. Complexity theory, Some problems, such as enumerating all permutations in
however, may be traced back to conceptual antecedents a resource allocation situation or nding the shortest
such as the ``philosophy of organism'' (Whitehead, path through a network, are very hard to solve in non-
1925), neural networks (McCulloch and Pitts, 1943), trivial cases. This rst form of algorithmic complexity is
cybernetics (Wiener, 1961), and cellular automata (von useful because it guides practitioners in their choice of
Neumann, 1966). Complexity theory also owes much to technique.
general systems theory given shared foci of anti-reduc- The second, more touted aspect of algorithmic
tionism and holistic appreciation of system intercon- complexity lies in information theory (Chaitin, 1992).
nectedness (von Bertalany, 1968). The link between This body of work identies complexity as the simplest
general systems theory and complexity is seldom rec- computational algorithm that can reproduce system
ognized (Phelan, 1999), possibly because the former was behavior. With information theory, one may condense
largely rejected by academics. During the rise of general the myriad interactions between system components
systems theory, some geographers found it potentially into simple measures. The use of information theory
useful as a means of modeling environmental systems ranges from classifying remotely sensed imagery
(Bennett and Chorley, 1978). Others, however, consid- (Eastman, 1999) to considering the role of ecological
ered it irrelevant to social concerns (Chisholm, 1967) community structure on biodiversity (Norton and
and, in general, geographers have abandoned systems Ulanowicz, 1992). Information theoretic concepts of
theory (Johnston, 1994). complexity take an epistemological cast when mental
If complexity theory is an outgrowth of previous experiments establish limits to knowledge. The brain,
work and of general systems theory in particular, what for instance, is a computing device with a limited in-
does complexity research oer that previous eorts did formation processing capacity and is therefore limited
not? First, complexity often concerns non-linear rela- to answering to certain kinds of problems (Traub,
tionships between constantly changing entities. Systems 1996).
theory, in contrast, studies static entities linked by linear The key diculty in applying algorithmic complexity
relationships dened by ows and stocks (e.g., of en- to social or environmental phenomena, especially when
ergy, information). Second, this stocks-and-ows per- positing computational limits of knowledge, is that it
spective emphasizes quantities of ow and not may incorrectly equate data with knowledge. Vast
necessarily their quality. Complexity research employs realms of human endeavor, such as lived experience and
techniques such as articial intelligence to examine meaning given to it, lie beyond algorithmic expressions.
qualitative characteristics such as the symbolic content Even broad forms of description, such as language, are
of communication. Third, complexity research concerns necessarily vague because meaning lies in varying in-
how complex behavior evolves or emerges from rela- scriptions and readings of texts, landscapes, or experi-
tively simple local interactions between system compo- ence (Barnes and Duncan, 1991). Critics of geographic
nents over time. Systems theory instead favors information science raise a similar issue with the short-
simplication and parameterization of ows and stocks, comings of computational representation of spatial
a process that assumes that the system exists in equi- phenomena (Pickles, 1995). Algorithmic conceptions of
librium and therefore negates the need to examine complexity allow demarcation of the boundaries of
changing relationships between system elements. Com- certain types of knowledge but certainly not others.
S.M. Manson / Geoforum 32 (2001) 405414 407

3. Deterministic complexity tractor of 1 1=a. Positive feedback is self-reinforcing


and results in one or more variables moving rapidly
Deterministic complexity lies in chaos and catastro- towards a point of no return, as when population dies
phe theories. In some respects, these theories are dier- out or grows indenitely. To provide an illustrative (and
ent, but they are similar in use and import. Chaos theory simplistic) example, Malthusian population dynamics
holds that there exists a ``true'' chaos in keeping with rely on positive feedback for explosive growth and
popular usage and a ``robust'' chaos that is seemingly negative feedback, due to resource shortages, for pop-
random but in fact is the manifestation of some acces- ulation decline.
sible, underlying order. Catastrophe theory deals with
systems that experience large and abrupt changes in
some characteristic due to a small change in another. 3.1.3. Sensitivity to initial conditions and bifurcation
The overall state of chaotic or catastrophic systems
3.1. What makes complexity deterministic? are sensitive to small, incremental changes in key vari-
ables. At rst glance, this tendency is at odds with the
Deterministic complexity has four key characteristics: use of simple formulae to describe deterministic systems.
(1) the use of deterministic mathematics and mathe- In the example used here so far, changing the value of a
matical attractors; (2) the notion of feedback; (3) sen- in the range 1 < a < 3 by a small amount changes the
sitivity to initial conditions and bifurcation; and (4) the overall result by a correspondingly small amount. The
idea of deterministic chaos and strange attractors. system is completely insensitive to the initial values of
either a or X when a < 1 or a > 4. Once set in motion,
3.1.1. Deterministic mathematics and attractors the outcome never varies, just the rate at which the
One may describe, and potentially understand, cha- population arrives at zero or expands endlessly.
otic or catastrophic systems in simple mathematical Under certain conditions, however, the system is
terms. The term deterministic complexity refers to the sensitive to initial conditions. This term refers to situa-
premise that a few key variables related through a set of tions where small changes in the initial system congu-
known equations can describe the behavior of a complex ration may lead to large, non-linear eects. The popular
system. Consider the equation for the standard logistic term ``buttery eect'' exemplies sensitivity to initial
model of population growth, as one might nd in an conditions, whereby the apping of a buttery's wings
introductory human geography or ecology course: can inuence far removed weather systems. With the
values of a examined so far, population converges on a
Xt1 aXt 1 Xt ; 1
single attractor 1 1=a, 0 or 1). When 3 < a < 4,
where future population Xt1 is dependent on the current however, the system oscillates between multiple attrac-
population Xt (0 < X < 1 and a growth rate parameter tors. The population moves through cycles of boom and
a 0 < a < 4. This formula, for the most part, is useful bust. Small shifts in the value of a lead to large and
for projecting population and does not seem very com- sudden shifts in the attractors for the value of X, com-
plex. pletely changing the periodicity of the population.
May (1976) found that for parameter values of a The potential for system variables to jump suddenly
ranging from 1 to 3, the population settles on a single from one attractor to another is termed bifurcation
value equal to 1 1=a regardless of the initial size of (Feigenbaum, 1980). Researchers have examined a va-
the population. For example, when a 2, the popula- riety of chaotic systems for bifurcation (Nijkamp and
tion settles on the value of 0.5 after several generations. Reggiani, 1990; Byrne, 1997). Catastrophic systems in
This value 1 1=a) is termed an attractor, a value to- particular are dened more by bifurcation than other
wards which a system variable tends to settle over time. characteristics of deterministic complexity. Catastrophic
Other attractors for this equation are the population attractors are two-dimensional curves or three-dimen-
dying out (X becomes zero when a < 1) and the popu- sional surfaces dened by the interaction of two or three
lation expanding endlessly (X approaches innity when system variables. Along most of a catastrophic attrac-
a > 4). tor, any change in one variable typically results in a
change of similar magnitude in other variables. Cata-
3.1.2. Feedback strophic attracters, however, have occasional disconti-
The simple mathematic equations of deterministic nuities where a small change in one variable results in a
complexity allow for dynamic behavior by incorporating large ``catastrophic'' change in another. Catastrophe
feedback. In our example, the future population Xt1 ) is attractors have been largely used to describe changes in
dependent on the present population Xt ). Negative natural phenomena, with the exception of a few at-
feedback occurs when changes in one variable forces tempts to portray change in social systems in cata-
itself or other key variables to settle on a stable value. strophic terms (Renfrew and Cooke, 1979; Lowe, 1985;
This is the case when the population settles on the at- Brown, 1995).
408 S.M. Manson / Geoforum 32 (2001) 405414

3.1.4. Deterministic chaos, strange attractors, and frac- lation growth example, for instance, where are the
tals variables for culture, the state, or migration? If we could
For any initial pairing of a and X examined so far, it nd and defend appropriate choices, how would we pick
is possible to identify distinct attractors. There is, just two or three? Similarly, a large amount of time se-
however, one key exception. When a 3:8, the popu- ries data is required to prove that a system has deter-
lation variable, X, becomes completely random and ministic complexity. Even when data exists, fewer
chaotic with no discernable attractor. There is no reason systems than anticipated are in fact deterministically
as such for this particular value; it is simply inherent to chaotic (Zimmer, 1999) or catastrophic (Back, 1997)
the system. In terms of chaos theory, the system is not because characterizing a human system through a few
truly chaotic because a single deterministic equation simple variables or deterministic equations is often just
underlies seemingly random behavior, so we term the too, in a word, simplistic (Kellert, 1993). There are also
system deterministically chaotic given its behavior when hazards in conating pattern with process, as visited in
a 3:8. Of course, there are millions of seemingly cha- debates over urban form or city rank-size rules. Urban
otic systems and discovering if an equation can describe land use, for instance, may have a fractal pattern but
any given system is dicult. Fortunately, while a de- this knowledge only goes so far in aiding our under-
terministically chaotic system may lack normal attrac- standing of how it came to be that way.
tors, it does possess at least one strange attractor, a value Admittedly, eects such as sensitivity to initial con-
or set of values towards which system variables tend ditions or strange attractors can spur new thinking
towards over time but never quite reach. To determine if about accepted phenomena, especially when used in an
a system possesses a strange attractor, one draws a analogical manner. Postmodernists have embraced de-
Poincare graph, which simply refers to removing time as terministic complexity in this way (Hayles, 1991). De-
one of the axes of a graph and instead plotting data terministic complexity is characterized by contextuality,
points (sampled at a regular temporal interval) along complexity, and contingency; these themes exemplify
dimensions described by system variables (see Mainzer, postmodernism (Warf, 1993). Sensitivity to initial con-
1996). A Poincare graph of a truly chaotic system ap- ditions and bifurcation undermine totalizing discourses
pears random. The graph of a deterministically chaotic by supporting unpredictability and the search for frag-
system, however, traces system variables moving along mentation and discontinuity. Cartwright (1991), for in-
endlessly dierent paths that are simultaneously con- stance, argues that urban planning should take into
strained to a regular, geometric region of the graph. This account chaos theory. Given the potential for small
region is the strange attractor for the system. Just as changes in one place to result in large changes elsewhere,
normal attractors are values towards which system planning must be sensitive to the transformative eect of
variables tend, strange attractors roughly delimit the local interactions. Postmodern techniques such as de-
possible values of system variables. construction may also draw on chaos theory through a
Finally, there are fractals, complicated self-referential shared focus on iteration and recursion as a means of
patterns that also happen to be strange attractors whose destabilizing systems (Hayles, 1989).
patterns remain unchanging regardless of the scale of The postmodern concern for focusing on local inter-
observation. The structure of a tree, for instance, is actions inuences geographic concepts of scale. A
fractal because the same branching arrangement is ap- commonly accepted notion of scale is the nested hier-
parent at scales ranging from the entire tree down to the archy, a set of areal extents in which it is assumed that
veins in its leaves. This property of fractals, scale-in- the sum of all components of one level, such as counties
variance, has led geographers to look for fractal patterns or consumers, produces one component at a larger scale,
in phenomena ranging from urban form to coastlines such as states or households (Haggett, 1965). In this
(White and Engelen, 1993; Pecknold et al., 1997). Re- kind of spatial hierarchy, local context ne-tunes large-
searchers hope to understand phenomena that have scale processes. In light of the buttery eect, however, a
fractal patterns because the processes that give rise to local action may directly aect those at a larger scale
these patterns may be operating across scales. If so, without moving through intermediary scales. Similarly,
understanding how a system works at one scale may local action, instead of being dampened out, may be-
lead to understanding how it works other scales (Man- come amplied through the non-linear interactions be-
delbrot, 1977). tween components across scales. The impact of
individual currency speculators on the economies of
3.2. Reections on deterministic complexity entire countries exemplies this interaction, as individ-
ual actions are quickly scaled up through nancial net-
Deterministic complexity is an interesting but marred works to have profound eects on large-scale
concept. It is hard to explain a seemingly chaotic system phenomena (Jeanne, 1997).
when we are limited to two or three key variables that Contrary to the postmodern view of the importance
dene deterministically complex systems. In the popu- of sensitivity to initial conditions, structuralist and
S.M. Manson / Geoforum 32 (2001) 405414 409

modernist conceptual frameworks contend that the 4.1.1. Relationships


ability of strange attractors to describe key system The heart of aggregate complexity lies in relationships
characteristics reduces the signicance of sensitivity to between components. In an economy, for example,
initial conditions. Approaches grounded in historical components are consumers, rms, and the state. In turn,
materialism, for instance, link bifurcation to emanci- they exchange and redistribute information, matter, and
patory social transformation and identify the Fordist energy. In ecology, key entities are ora and fauna with
mode of regulation with the boundedness of strange relationships largely dened through matter and energy
attractors (Harvey and Reed, 1994; Byrne, 1997). In this exchanges.
view, socioeconomic systems are largely xed in their A complex system is dened more by relationships
mechanisms but can exist in several states, each having than by its constituent parts. A single person in an
an associated attractor. Fundamentally changing how economy can consume and produce goods and knowl-
the system plays out in a given locality lies less with edge, boycott rms, and contribute to the underground
individual actions and more with attempts to change the economy. A tree in an ecosystem is important to bio-
size of attractors and opportunities for bifurcation geochemical processes. Understanding and tracing the
(Byrne, 1998). Research on foreign trade and interna- relationships of a single entity is dicult, while tracing
tional development also uses the concept of strange at- them in an entire system verges on the impossible. Given
tractors and deterministic complexity (Savit, 1993; the number and variety of these relationships, they
Keen, 1997), as does work attempting to explain the extend beyond simple feedback into higher order, non-
decline of political systems in catastrophic terms (Ren- linear processes not amenable to modeling with tradi-
frew and Cooke, 1979; Lowe, 1985). tional techniques (Costanza et al., 1993).
Despite some advances, deterministic complexity is Sub-systems and individual components typically
still dicult to apply to social phenomena. Convincing have functions or goals, but given the complexity of
examples are largely limited to work in natural science relationships between components, it is impossible to
or physical geography (Prigogine and Stengers, 1984; characterize the system on the whole as having a unied
Philips, 1993). Social science has been far less forth- purpose. This is apparent for either an economy or
coming with convincing applications, although there are ecosystem. They may serve functions such as resource
some thought provoking exceptions (e.g., Wong and redistribution or maintenance of an atmosphere but they
Fotheringham, 1990; Krider and Weinberg, 1997). In- lack design.
stead, deterministic complexity serves as an intellectual Similarly, sub-systems and components are largely
foil. There is a limit, however, as seen in the tension limited to local interactions. There is no omniscience or
between those who see deterministic complexity as a constantly updated common body of information.
means of understanding complex systems through at- Apart from Gaia theory, it is hard to argue that any one
tractors and others who contend that sensitivity to ini- ecological component or sub-system ``knows'' what
tial conditions limits understanding and prediction. In other components are doing. Similarly, the notion of the
conclusion, deterministic complexity is interesting but all-knowing, rational homo economicus is increasingly
marred by shortcomings. under siege for its assumption of ubiquitous information
and insensitivity to local context (Cook and Levi, 1990).

4. Aggregate complexity 4.1.2. Internal structure


The components of a system and their relationships
Complexity research increasingly considers systems are not an undierentiated mass. Relationships of dif-
of linked components, or aggregate complexity. Algo- fering strengths between component parts dene the
rithmic and deterministic complexity rely on simple internal structure of a system. Components with espe-
mathematical equations and a number of assumptions cially tight connections form sub-systems, so even
of how complex systems work. Aggregate complexity homogenous components can support internal diver-
instead attempts to access the holism and synergy re- sity through realignment of relationships to create
sulting from the interaction of system components. non-identical sub-systems. Economic entities form
sub-systems according to their relationships in space,
4.1. Key attributes of aggregate complexity competitive niches, and shared consumer preferences.
Ecological entities form sub-systems within species or
In order to understand aggregate complexity, it is outside of species (e.g., an ecotope). Any given compo-
necessary to explore a key set of interrelated concepts nent can belong to multiple sub-systems. A single per-
that dene a complex system: relationships between son, for instance, can simultaneously be part of a family,
entities; internal structure and surrounding environ- union, investment club, and regional economy. A tree is
ment; learning and emergent behavior; and the dierent part of a larger community of trees through mechanisms
means by which complex systems change and grow. such as seed dispersal and has symbiotic relationships
410 S.M. Manson / Geoforum 32 (2001) 405414

with other plants and animals (Allen and Hoekstra, whereby system-wide characteristics do not result from
1992). superposition (i.e., additive eects of system compo-
nents) but instead from interactions among components
4.1.3. Environment (Lansing and Kremer, 1993). An economy has emergent
A complex system owes its existence to relationships qualities such as volatility and investor ``herd behavior''
with its environment, dened as anything outside of the that are commonly attributed to irrationality or imper-
system, although this division may not be sharp. Natu- fect markets but in fact are intrinsic to rational, local
ral resources, international markets, and human desires interactions and their non-linear consequences (Andre-
may be considered external to a national economy but oni and Miller, 1995).
the boundaries are permeable. External to an ecosystem Emergent phenomena may lie beyond our ability to
are abiotic aspects of the earth such as its crust and predict or control. There is certainly enough under-
climate. Regardless of the actual boundary between a standing of an economy to allow for intervention in
system and the environment, the former passes infor- major sub-systems with an eye towards changing some
mation, matter and energy through its internal structure. emergent quality, such as regulating a major industry in
The actions and interactions of system components order to stabilize prices. It is dicult, however, to an-
eventually create outow from the system into the en- ticipate changes beyond the short term because other
vironment. components of the system adjust to this intervention in
addition to other changes in the environment (You-
4.1.4. Learning and memory ssefmir and Huberman, 1997). Similarly, as we increas-
A complex system is not beholden to the environment ingly discover to our chagrin, any single change to an
it actively shapes, reacts, and anticipates. A system ecosystem can have far-reaching, large-scale eects due
``remembers'' through the persistence of internal struc- to not understanding emergence from complexity
ture (Holland, 1992). Components and sub-systems with (Lansing and Kremer, 1993).
the capacity to accommodate the inux of energy,
matter, and information from the environment will 4.1.6. Change and evolution
grow. Regularly occurring external relationships en- A complex system constantly changes, largely
courage the growth of the same set of components and through three dierent types of transition. First, a key
sub-systems. The memory of an economic system exists characteristic of a complex system is self-organization,
in various places, such as business plans and the expe- the property that allows it to change its internal struc-
rience of individuals. Ecological information lies largely ture in order to better interact with its environment.
in the form varying congurations and density of rela- Self-organization allows a system to learn through
tionships between and within species. piecemeal changes in internal structure.
A complex system can deal with truly novel situations Second, a system becomes dissipative when outside
because it has a wide array of internal components and forces or internal perturbations drive it to a highly
sub-systems linked by complex relationships. Some unorganized state before suddenly crossing into one
subset of these components may have some ability to with more organization (Schieve and Allen, 1982).
accommodate a novel relationship. In the rare cases Economies can be dissipative when confronting large
when no suitable components or sub-systems exist, the shifts in the nature of their relationships with the en-
system cannot respond to new relationships with the vironment. Introduction of new technologies, such as
environment, with potentially catastrophic results. in the industrial revolution, can spur radical change in
Concern for this kind of system collapse lies in the drive the internal structure of an economy (Harvey and
to protect biodiversity. The destruction of complex, di- Reed, 1994). The work of Holling (1978, 1995) illus-
verse internal relationships may lead to a lack of resil- trates how small disturbances such as pest infestations
ience and adaptability in ecosystems. When monocrops or re can trigger large-scale redistribution of resources
replace mixed agriculture or forest, for instance, the and connectivity within the internal structure of an
ecosystem is more susceptible to rapid and potentially ecosystem.
adverse shifts in the environment, such as the intro- Third, the term self-organized criticality refers to the
duction of foreign species or climate change (Wilson, ability of complex systems to balance between ran-
1988). domness and stasis. Instead of occasionally weathering a
crisis, a system can reach a critical point where its in-
4.1.5. Emergence ternal structure lies on the brink of collapsing without
The capacities of a complex system are greater than actually doing so (Bak and Chen, 1991). Self-organized
the sum of its constituent parts. A system can have criticality is a form of self-organization where the rate of
emergent qualities that are not analytically tractable internal restructuring is almost too rapid for the system
from the attributes of internal components (Baas and to accommodate but necessary for its eventual survival
Emmeche, 1997). Emergence is a function of synergism, (Scheinkman and Woodford, 1994). Research on self-
S.M. Manson / Geoforum 32 (2001) 405414 411

organized criticality is largely restricted to ecological between self-organized criticality and the view of for-
and biogeophysical systems (e.g., Andrade Jr. et al., ces of Lyotard (1984), creating social diversity and
1995; Correig et al., 1997) but there is a small and novelty through dissension and destabilization of the
growing body of work on urban and economic systems status quo (Funtowitcz and Ravetz, 1994; Cilliers,
(Sanders, 1996; Allen, 1997). 1998). The constant repositioning of entities and re-
lationships within a complex system supports the
4.2. Reections on aggregate complexity postmodern view of a multiplicity of localized, yet
networked, social and political discourses. The mean-
The chief value of aggregate complexity is its ing of language and knowledge is not crystallized and
challenge to conventional notions of stability and centralized but instead distributed and created through
change. Science in general sees systems of intercon- the interaction and competition of dierent viewpoints
nected elements, such as economies or ecologies, as (Cliord, 1988; Cilliers, 1998). Similarly, aggregate
stable entities. This view has been critical to the suc- complexity illustrates how relationships are more im-
cess of science. It is also useful, however, to see portant than attributes in dening the nature of
complex systems as constantly changing their internal components. This insight supports reconceptualization
structure and external environment through self-orga- of identity and representation, whereby a person is not
nization, dissipative behavior, and self-organized crit- limited to a singular identity but instead is situated in
icality. a web of relative power relations (Gibson-Graham,
Mainstream economics, for instance, studies stability 1993).
and repeated patterns, while complexity research is The notion of aggregate complexity creating emer-
interested in ``multiple equilibria, non-predictability, gence potentially addresses the micromacro distinc-
lock-in, ineciency, historical path dependence, and tion in issues such as the relationship between agency
asymmetry'' (Arthur, 1999, p. 108). Complexity also and structure. Social institutions, for instance, are both
questions the long-held assumption that ecosystems artifacts and dynamic processes that constitute, and are
evolve towards an unchanging ``climax'' structure constituted by, regularized behavior of their compo-
(Worster, 1985). It may be more fruitful to consider nent parts (Ostrom, 1990). There is a growing body of
ecological landscapes as existing in a constant state of research linking aggregate complexity to institutional
ux (Goerner, 1994; Philips, 1999). and organizational behavior using computer simula-
Unfortunately, it is dicult to employ insights gran- tions based on systems of software agents (Conte et al.,
ted by aggregate complexity. Dening the boundaries 1997).
and components of a system is problematic. It is also Another signicant body of research lies in exploring
necessary to adequately defend and characterize what emergence with cellular automata. These tessellations
constitutes learning, self-organization, and adaptation (e.g., grids) represent how the state of some phenome-
(Rapport, 1991). A conceptually coherent view of a non changes in time according to rules based on local-
complex system is hard to link to reality. Equilibrium- ized interactions of entities. Geographers have readily
oriented mathematics is not suited to dynamic, histori- adopted cellular automata given a conceptual resonance
cally dependent or transient phenomenon. Emergent with cellular geography (Wagner, 1997) and GeoAlge-
social phenomena can disappear when one reduces the bra (Couclelis, 1997). Cellular automata are used to
system into components or uses too many statistical model phenomena ranging from ecosystems (Hogeweg,
assumptions (Arthur, 1994). 1988; Ermentrout and Edelstein-Keshet, 1993) to urban
A potential answer to these methodological dicul- morphology (White and Engelen, 1993; Clarke et al.,
ties is the increasing sophistication of computer simu- 1996; Couclelis, 1997).
lation tools that allow ``exploratory simulation'' (Conte Although research on how macro-scale phenomena
and Gilbert, 1995; 4). Silicon-based simulation is a arise from micro-interaction continues apace, less ex-
manifestation of possible system outcomes that are not amined is the eect of macro-structure on the micro-
preordained and deterministic (Thrift, 1999). This said, scale. Seeing social norms as emerging from agent
model results can reect underlying programming more interaction, for instance, does not adequately address
than the phenomena modeled. Much work remains how norms aect agents (e.g., Blume, 1996; Gintis,
undone on means of classication, measurement, and 1997). Some denitions of emergence go so far as to
validation, particularly when distinguishing legitimate necessitate that lower level elements are unaware of their
results from modeling artifacts (Huberman and Glance, role in emergent phenomena (Forrest, 1991). As a result,
1993). complexity-based human system surrogates can fail be-
Aggregate complexity is not limited to computer cause they do not allow reexivity or individuals who
simulations. Postmodern and poststructural perspec- reason about features of which they are part.
tives link complexity to knowledge, language, and As with other forms of complexity, aggregate
epistemology. Several authors leverage the resonance complexity oers insight at a cost. It oers valuable
412 S.M. Manson / Geoforum 32 (2001) 405414

commentary on emergence, equilibrium, and change. At References


the same time, despite the potential of simulation, ag-
gregate complexity must overcome methodological Allen, P.M., 1997. Cities and Regions as Self-Organizing Systems:
Models of Complexity. Gordon and Breach, London.
shortcomings. More importantly, its conceptual contri-
Allen, T.F.H., Hoekstra, T.W., 1992. Toward a Unied Ecology.
butions to the larger body of science are still unclear. On Columbia University Press, New York.
one extreme, aggregate complexity dovetails well with Andrade Jr., J.S., Wainer, I., Moreira, J.E., 1995. Self-organized
postmodern conceptions of the world. On the other, a criticality in the El Nino southern oscillation. Physica A 215 (3),
sociobiological form of aggregate complexity holds that 331338.
Andreoni, J., Miller, J.H., 1995. Auctions with articial adaptive
the evolution of social structure evolves from the im-
agents. Games and Econ. Behav. 10, 3964.
perative of individual survival (Dawson, 1996; Pearson, Arthur, W.B., 1994. Inductive reasoning and bounded rationality. Am.
1996). The discordance between these views underlines Econ. Rev., Papers Proc. 84 (2), 406411.
the need to couple complexity-based research with other Arthur, W.B., 1999. Complexity and the economy. Science 284 (5411),
conceptions of human agency and the role of social 107109.
Baas, N.A., Emmeche, C., 1997. On Emergence and Explanation.
phenomena such as institutions and culture.
Santa Fe Institute, Santa Fe, NM.
Back, K.W., 1997. Chaos and complexity: Necessary myths. In: Eve,
R.A., Horsfall, S., Lee, M.E. (Eds.), Chaos, Complexity, and
5. Conclusion Sociology. Sage, Thousand Oaks, CA, pp. 3949.
Bak, P., Chen, K., 1999. Self-organized criticality. Sci. Am. January,
4653.
The value of complexity exists in the eye of its be- Barnes, T., Duncan, J., 1991. Writing Worlds: Discourse, Text, and
holder. For some it is merely a passing fad, for others an Metaphor. Routledge, London, UK.
interesting complement to accepted conceptual frame- Bennett, R.J., Chorley, R.J., 1978. Environmental Systems: Philosophy,
works, and for others it is a pioneering break from a Analysis, and Control. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
Blume, L.E., 1996. Population Games. Santa Fe Institute, Santa Fe,
moribund Newtonian worldview. Identical ndings or
NM.
phenomena can lead to radically dierent interpreta- Brown, C., 1995. Chaos and Catastrophe Theories. Sage, Thousand
tions. How far can we extend the epistemological cor- Oaks, CA.
ollaries of algorithmic complexity? Does deterministic Byrne, D., 1997. Chaotic places or complex places: Cities in a post-
complexity allow or prevent prediction and control of industrial era. In: Westwood, S., Williams, J. (Eds.), Imagining
Cities. Routledge, London, pp. 5072.
complex systems? Does aggregate complexity support
Byrne, D., 1998. Complexity Theory and the Social Sciences. Routl-
the role of individuality and creativity or does it point to edge, London.
biological determinism in human aairs? Cartwright, T.J., 1991. Planning and chaos theory. J. Am. Planning
Answering these questions and others should be a Assoc. 57, 4456.
priority for geographers and planners. Our work oers Chaitin, G.J., 1992. Information, Randomness, and Incompleteness.
World Scientic, Singapore.
both the theoretical dimensions and empirical knowl-
Chisholm, M., 1967. General systems theory and geography. Trans.
edge necessary to conduct complexity research. Key is- Inst. Br. Geographers 42, 4552.
sues surrounding complexity in general include: (1) the Cilliers, P., 1998. Complexity and Postmodernism: Understanding
need to understand better the dierent kinds of com- Complex Systems. Routledge, New York, NY.
plexity theory; (2) provision of data and techniques Clarke, K.C., Hoppen, S., Gaydos, L.J., 1996. A self-modifying
cellular automaton model of historical urbanization in the San
amenable to complexity research; (3) proper interpre-
Francisco Bay area. Environ. Planning B 24, 247261.
tation of complexity theory, especially with regard to Cliord, J., 1988. The Predicament of Culture. Harvard University
human systems; and (4) exploration of the ontological Press, Cambridge, MA.
and epistemological corollaries of complexity. In return Conte, R., Gilbert, N., 1995. Computer simulation for social theory.
for addressing these issues, complexity oers a host of In: Gilbert, N., Conte, R. (Eds.), Articial Societies: The Computer
Simulation of Social Life. UCL Press, London, pp. 115.
new approaches to the study of economic, political,
Conte, R., Hegselmann, R., Terna, P. (Eds.), 1997. Simulating Social
social and environmental systems. Phenomena. Springer, Berlin.
Cook, K.S., Levi, M. (Eds.), 1990. The Limits of Rationality.
University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL.
Correig, A.M., Urquizu, M., Vila, J., 1997. Aftershock series of event
Acknowledgements
February 18, 1996: an interpretation in terms of self-organized
criticality. J. Geophys. Res. B 102 (12), 2740727420.
This work is supported in part by National Science Costanza, R., Wainger, L., Folke, C., et al., 1993. Modeling complex
Foundation Grant Number 9521914 through the Car- ecological economic systems: toward an evolutionary, dynamic
negie Mellon University Center for Integrated Study of understanding of people and nature. Bioscience 43 (8), 545555.
Couclelis, H., 1997. From cellular automata to urban models: new
the Human Dimensions of Global Change. The author
principles for model development and implementation. Environ.
gratefully acknowledges the assistance of Dr. D.P. An- Planning B 24, 163174.
gel and Dr. B.L. Turner II. Responsibility for the Dawson, D., 1996. The origins of war: biological and anthropological
opinions expressed is solely that of the author. theories. History and Theory 35 (1), 128.
S.M. Manson / Geoforum 32 (2001) 405414 413

Eastman, R., 1999. IDRISI32. Clark University, Worcester, MA. Mainzer, K., 1996. Thinking in Complexity: The Complex Dynamics
Ermentrout, G.B., Edelstein-Keshet, L., 1993. Cellular automata of Matter, Mind, and Mankind. Springer, New York.
approaches to biological modeling. J. Theoret. Biol. 160 (1), Mandelbrot, B.B., 1977. Fractals. W.H. Freeman, San Francisco, CA.
97113. May, R., 1976. Simple mathematical models with very complicated
Feigenbaum, M.J., 1980. Universal behavior in nonlinear systems. Los dynamics. Nature 261, 459467.
Alamos Sci. 1, 427. McCulloch, W.S., Pitts, W., 1943. A logical calculus of the ideas
Forrest, S. (Ed.), 1991. Emergent Computation: Self-Organization, immanent in nervous activity. Bull. Math. Biophys. 5, 115137.
Collective, and Cooperative Phenomena in Natural and Articial Nijkamp, P., Reggiani, A., 1990. Logit models and chaotic behaviour:
Computing Networks. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. a new perspective. Environ. Planning A 22, 14551467.
Funtowitcz, S.O., Ravetz, J.R., 1994. Emergent complex systems. Norton, B.G., Ulanowicz, R.E., 1992. Scale and biodiversity policy: a
Futures 26 (6), 568582. hierarchical approach. Ambio 21 (3), 244249.
Gibson-Graham, J.K., 1993. Stued if I Know: Reections on Ostrom, E., 1990. Governing the Global Commons: The Evolution of
Postmodern Feminist Research. Department of Geology and Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge University Press,
Geography, University of Massachusetts, Amherst, MA. Cambridge, UK.
Gintis, H., 1997. A Markov Model of Production, Trade, and Money: Pearson, D.E., 1996. Sociology and biosociology. Am. Sociol. 27 (2),
Theory and Articial Life Simulation. Santa Fe Institute, Santa Fe, 820.
NM. Pecknold, S., Lovejoy, S., Schertzer, D., et al., 1997. Multifractals and
Goerner, S., 1994. The Evolving Ecological Universe. Gordon and resolution dependence of remotely sensed data: GSI to GIS. In:
Breach Science, New York. Quattrochi, D.A., Goodchild, M.F. (Eds.), Scale in Remote
Haggett, P., 1965. Locational Analysis in Human Geography. Edward Sensing and GIS. Lewis, New York, pp. 361394.
Arnold, London. Phelan, S.E., 1999. Note on the correspondence between complexity
Harvey, D.L., Reed, M.H., 1994. The evolution of dissipative social and systems theory. Systemic Practice and Action Res. 12 (3), 237
systems. J. Soc. Evol. Syst. 17 (4), 371411. 238.
Hayles, N.K., 1989. Chaos as orderly disorder: shifting ground in Philips, J.D., 1993. Spatial-domain chaos in landscapes. Geogr. Anal.
contemporary literature. N. Literary Hist. 20, 305322. 25 (2), 101117.
Hayles, N.K., 1991. Complex dynamics in literature and science. In: Philips, J.D., 1999. Divergence, convergence, and self-organization in
Hayles, N.K. (Ed.), Chaos and Order: Complex Dynamics in landscapes. Ann. Assoc. Am. Geographers 89 (3), 466488.
Literature and Science. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL, Pickles, J., 1995. Ground Truth: The Social Implications of GIS. The
pp. 133. Guilford Press, New York.
Hogeweg, P., 1988. Cellular automata as a paradigm for ecological Prigogine, I., Stengers, I., 1984. Order Out of Chaos: Man's New
modelling. Appl. Math. Comput. 27 (1), 81100. Dialogue with Nature. Bantam, New York.
Holland, J.H., 1992. Complex adaptive systems. Daedalus 121 (1), Rapport, D.J., 1991. Myths in the foundations of economics and
1730. ecology. Biol. J. Linn. Soc. 44, 185202.
Holling, C.S. (Ed.), 1978. Adaptive Environmental Assessment and Renfrew, C., Cooke, K.L. (Eds.), 1979. Transformations: Mathemat-
Learning. Wiley, London. ical Approaches to Cultural Change.
Holling, C.S., 1995. Sustainability: The cross-scale dimension. In: Sanders, L., 1996. Dynamic modelling of urban systems. In: Fischer,
Murasinghe, M., Shearer, W. (Eds.), Dening and Measuring M., Scholten, H.J., Unwin, D. (Eds.), Spatial Analytical Perspec-
Sustainability. The World Bank, Washington, DC, pp. 6575. tives on GIS. Taylor and Francis, London, pp. 229244.
Horgan, J., 1995. From complexity to perplexity. Sci. Am. 272, Sarder, Z., Ravetz, J.R., 1994. Complexity: fad or future?. Futures 26
104109. (6), 563567.
Huberman, B.A., Glance, N.S., 1993. Evolutionary games and Savit, R., 1993. Chaos on the trading oor. In: Hall, N. (Ed.),
computer simulations. Proc. Nat. Acad. Sci. 90 (16), 77167719. Exploring Chaos: A Guide to the New Science of Disorder.
Jeanne, O., 1997. Are currency crises self-fullling? A test. J. Int. Econ. Norton, New York, pp. 174183.
43 (3/4), 263286. Scheinkman, J.A., Woodford, M., 1994. Self-organized criticality and
Johnston, R.J., 1994. General systems theory. In: Johnston, R.J., economic uctuations. Am. Econ. Rev. 84 (2), 417421.
Gregory, D., Smith, D. (Eds.), The Dictionary of Human Geog- Schieve, W.C., Allen, P.M. (Eds.), 1982. Self-Organization and
raphy. Basil Blackwell, Oxford, UK, pp. 215216. Dissipative Structures: Applications in the Physical and Social
Keen, S., 1997. From stochastics to complexity in models of economic Sciences. University of Texas Press, Austin, TX.
instability. Nonlinear Dyn. Psychol. and Life Sci. 1 (2), 151171. Science, 1999. Complex systems. Science 284 (5411), 79107.
Kellert, S.H., 1993. In the Wake of Chaos. University of Chicago Thrift, N., 1999. The place of complexity. Theory, Culture and Soc. 16
Press, Chicago, IL. (3), 3169.
Krider, R.E., Weinberg, C.B., 1997. Spatial competition and bounded Traub, J.F., 1996. The Unknown and the Unknowable. Santa Fe
rationality: retailing on the edge of chaos. Geogr. Anal. 29 (1), Institute, Santa Fe, NM.
1734. von Bertalany, L., 1968. General Systems Theory: Foundation,
Lansing, J.S., Kremer, J.N., 1993. Emergent properties of Balinese Development, Applications. Allen Lane, London.
water temple networks: coadaptation on a rugged tness landscape. von Neumann, J., 1966. Theory of Self-Reproducing Automata.
Am. Anthropol. 95 (1), 97114. University of Illinois Press, Champaign-Urbana.
Lewin, R., 1992. Complexity: Life at the Edge of Chaos. MacMillan, Wagner, D.F., 1997. Cellular automata and geographic information
New York. systems. Environ. Planning B 24, 219234.
Lo Presti, A., 1996. Futures research and complexity: a critical Warf, B., 1993. Postmodernism and the localities debate: ontological
analysis from the perspective of social science. Futures 28 (10), questions and epistemological implications. Tijdschr. Economische
891902. Sociale Geograf. 84 (3), 162168.
Lowe, J., 1985. The Dynamics of Collapse: A Systems Simulation of White, R., Engelen, G., 1993. Cellular automata and fractal urban
the Classic Maya Collapse. University of New Mexico Press, form: a cellular modelling approach to the evolution of urban land-
Albuquerque, NM. use patterns. Environ. Planning D 25, 11751199.
Lyotard, J.-F., 1984. The Postmodern Condition: A Report on Whitehead, A.N., 1925. Science and the Modern World. Macmillan,
Knowledge. University of Minnesota Press, Minneapolis, MN. New York.
414 S.M. Manson / Geoforum 32 (2001) 405414

Wiener, N., 1961. Cybernetics: Or, Control and Communication in the Worster, D., 1985. Nature's Economy: A History of Ecological Ideas.
Animal and the Machine. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Wilson, E.O., 1988. Biodiversity. National Academy Press, Washing- Youssefmir, M., Huberman, B.A., 1997. Clustered volatility in
ton, DC. multiagent dynamics. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 31 (1), 101118.
Wong, D.W.S., Fotheringham, A.S., 1990. Urban systems as examples Zimmer, C., 1999. Life after chaos. Science 284 (5411), 8386.
of bounded chaos: exploring the relationship between fractal
dimension, rank-size, and rural-to-urban migration. Geogr. Ann.
B 72 (3), 8999.

View publication stats

You might also like