You are on page 1of 25

Asian Financial Crisis

- Thai baht lost its peg with the dollar


- high-flying stockbroker who was reduced to selling sandwiches, and a businesswoman whose
boss told her to take care of the work for me before hanging himself.
- In Hong Kong, Japan and South Korea, 10,400 people killed themselves as a result of the
crisis, according to subsequent research.)
- In Thailand the financial calamity became known as the tom yum kung crisis, after the local
hot-and-sour soup, presumably because it was such a bitter and searing experience.
- With the exception of Hong Kong, they no longer rely on a hard peg to the dollar to anchor
inflation, giving their currencies more room to move.
- On the eve of the crisis, Thailand, for example, was importing far more than it exported,
borrowing from foreigners to bridge the gap. In 1996, its current-account deficit amounted to
about 8% of GDP. Twenty years later, it had a surplus of over 11%.
- After all, Asia did not see the 1997 crisis coming precisely because it thought it had learned
the lessons from earlier crises. Unlike the profligate Latin Americans, for example, the Asian
countries had high national saving rates, limited public debt and budget surpluses. In 1996,
Thailands central-government debt was under 5% of GDP.
- He argues that even countries that maintain floating exchange rates and have little visible
foreign-currency debt can suffer financial strain (as in 2013), if their companies foreign
subsidiaries borrow too much.
- Unfortunately, when the Federal Reserve tightens, the dollar strengthens and the offshore
markets become less accommodating, this process can go into reverse. Multinationals that
suddenly cannot raise money abroad make greater demands on domestic banks, withdrawing
deposits and requesting loans. This tightens financial conditions, even if the local central
bank, proud of its floating exchange rate and independent monetary policy, has not itself
raised interest rates.
- Before the crisis, Asia maintained extraordinary rates of capital expenditure by supplementing
its own saving with saving imported from the rest of the world. After the crisis, it curbed that
net foreign borrowing, but only by slashing investment

Lessons learned:
- Asians saw a lot of restructuring, renovation of investment process, people's request for
distribution righteousness i.e. democracy and regime changes. And, many sound assets were
sold in the lower price to foreign buyers to get foreign money, i.e. the dollar. Since then,
many Asian democracies turned to be extremely aiming for foreign currency and extremely
cautious about foreign import. The democratic mercantilism and nationalism emerged. Still,
the democracy includes nationalism.
In 1997, Asian countries learned a lesson. They accumulated as many foreign currencies. And
China did too. The demand for foreign currency increased and US money export business
exploded until 2007, when business cycle changed. Asians saw only simultaneously, both US
and UK fell into financial problem, and somehow EU finance industry that had traded the US
mortgages fell into trouble too. And then those foreign currencies nearly doubled based on
certain imaginary credit (they call asset) as if their asset clones had been somewhere. And
the comparative weight of Asian foreign reserves lowered to half and the needs for foreign
currency increased again. And now, the Asian businesses meet another risk of foreign
subordinate's financial shortage because they invested in the foreign country to employ the
foreigners who are not competitive or profitable than Asian workers.
Perhaps the second big lesson Asian countries now learned. Yuan must be the international
currency, and there should be balance for international valuation on assets of Asian
countries. Then, Indian rupee, Russian Ruble and eventually every Asian currency can value
for itself (to some degree) in the global trade.

- The countries involved in the crisis have responded by improving their


economic frameworks. Financial oversight, macroeconomic frameworks,
and domestic competitiveness have been greatly strengthened. As a result
the region has experienced solid growth in the intervening period and
proved resilient in the global financial. The region has also developed
stronger collective institutions. The crisis gave impetus to efforts to become
less reliant on the International Monetary Funddue to profound mistakes
made in its response to the crisis. The ASEAN+3 grouping, including China,
Japan, and Korea has developed its own $240 billion currency swap
arrangement that has capacity to assist its members facing international
liquidity issues.

- Japan and China have separately offered bilateral currency swaps that could
be used in a crisis situation. These arrangements have yet to be put to the
test, but it would be a mistake to underestimate the extent of regional
resolve to better manage future crises.

- At the same time the IMF has itself learnt many lessons from the crisis.
Financial crises are different from conventional macroeconomic crises
brought about by lax macroeconomic policy. They require failing
institutions to be rapidly cleaned up or capitalised, supported by
macroeconomic policies to assist in coping with the demand hit. This lesson
was of course reinforced by the global financial crisis a decade later. The
IMF has also understood the need to ensure its programs focus on issues that
are critical to recovery, rather than detailed lists of conditions.

- Twenty years on new challenges remain in the region.


- CURRENT CHALLENGES
- Growth in the region continues to be strong and there is every reason to
think this will continue in the near term. However, there are also common
risks to regional growth over the short and medium term. High and growing
corporate debt and credit in China pose threats to regional growth if these
are not successfully managed. Japans macroeconomic policy is fully
extended, leaving little capacity to respond to new shocks, while
geopolitical risks including on the Korean peninsula could have economic
reverberations.
- A strengthening U.S. economy is obviously positive for the region.
However, as monetary policy normalises, financial conditions could tighten
as markets over-react, or in response to badly timed fiscal stimulus or
protectionist policies. In the background, rising volumes and volatility in
capital flows are seen as a key risk to the region.

- The most important response is to ensure solid financial and foreign


exchange buffers in regional economies, and macroeconomic policy space.
Australia and other countries in region need to make good use of economic
and policy dialogues in international and regional institutions to manage
common economic risks.

- The common risks facing the region means that we need good global risk-
sharing arrangements. The IMF needs to continue to improve its reputation
as a trusted partner, so it is an early rather than last resort. The location of
next years IMF/World Bank annual meetings in Bali, the first in emerging
Asia since the crisis, is an opportunity.

- KEEPING A STRONG IMF BALANCE SHEET

- And Australia and others in the region should work to ensure the IMF
balance sheet remains strong. About half of IMF lending firepower comes
from borrowings, which expire around 2020, and proposals to lift the
permanent quota (or equity) of the fund will face political challenges. This
region has as much interest as any in ensuring that these important global
public good remains adequately resourced.

- Regional swap mechanisms need to be further strengthened so that they can


be sure to work smoothly in a crisis, including with the IMF.

- Australia committed bilateral resources in the Asian crisis and after the
global financial crisis. There is an opportunity for us to take the initiative
and engage with others in the region about how we might cooperate in
future crisis responses.

- This requires a keen awareness that even though there are few signs of
smoke right now, we need well-stocked and effective fire engines.
The collapse of the Thai baht in July 1997 was followed by an
unprecedented financial crisis in East Asia, from which these
economies are still struggling to recover. A great deal of effort has
been devoted to trying to understand its causes. One view is that
there was nothing inherently wrong with East Asian economies,
which have historically performed very well. These economies
experienced a surge in capital inflows to finance productive
investments that made them vulnerable to a financial panic. That
panicand inadequate policy responsestriggered a region-wide
financial crisis and the economic disruption that followed (Sachs
and Radelet 1998).

An alternative view is that weaknesses in Asian financial systems


were at the root of the crisis. These weaknesses were caused
largely by the lack of incentives for effective risk management
created by implicit or explicit government guarantees against failure
(Moreno, Pasadilla, and Remolona 1998 and others cited below).
The weaknesses of the financial sector were masked by rapid
growth and accentuated by large capital inflows, which were partly
encouraged by pegged exchange rates.

While the two views are not mutually exclusive, their policy
implications vary greatly. If a panic unrelated to fundamentals fully
explains Asias financial crisis, reforms in the economic structure or
in financial sector policy are not essential in planning Asias
recovery. If, however, weaknesses in the financial sector were
important contributors to the crisis, reforms are indeed essential. To
shed further light on this question, this Economic Letter briefly
reviews Asias recent financial crisis and the two alternative views
of its cause.

Boom and bust in Asia

Operating in an environment of fiscal and monetary restraint, most


of East Asia enjoyed high savings and investment rates, robust
growth, and moderate inflation for several decades. Starting in the
second half of the 1980s, rapid growth was accompanied by sharp
increases in asset values, notably stock and land prices, and in
some cases by rapid increases in short-term borrowing from
abroad.
After the mid-1990s a series of external shocks (the devaluation of
the Chinese remnimbi and the Japanese yen and the sharp decline
in semiconductor prices) adversely affected export revenues and
contributed to slowing economic activity and declining asset prices
in a number of Asian economies. In Thailand, these events were
accompanied by pressures in the foreign exchange market and the
collapse of the Thai baht in July 1997.

The events in Thailand prompted investors to reassess and test the


robustness of currency pegs and financial systems in the region.
The result was a wave of currency depreciations and stock market
declines, first affecting Southeast Asia, then spreading to the rest of
the region. In the year after collapse of the baht peg, the value of
the most affected East Asian currencies fell 35-83% against the
U.S. dollar (measured in dollars per unit of the Asian currency), and
the most serious stock declines were as great as 40-60%.

Disruptions in bank and borrower balance sheets have led to


widespread bankruptcies and an interruption in credit flows in the
most severely affected economies. As a result, short-term economic
activity has slowed or contracted severely in the most affected
economies.

Interpreting the crisis

The economic shocks affecting East Asia were not followed by a


normal cyclical downturn, but what some describe as runs on
financial systems and currencies. Some argue that these runs
reflected a classic financial panic that did not reflect poor economic
policies or institutional arrangements. As is well known, even well-
managed banks or financial intermediaries are vulnerable to panics,
because they traditionally engage in maturity transformation. That
is, banks accept deposits with short maturities (say, three months)
to finance loans with longer maturities (say, a year or longer).
Maturity transformation is beneficial because it can make more
funds available to productive long-term investors than they would
otherwise receive. Under normal conditions, banks have no
problem managing their portfolios to meet expected withdrawals.
However, if all depositors decided to withdraw their funds from a
given bank at the same time, as in the case of a panic, the bank
would not have enough liquid assets to meet its obligations,
threatening the viability of an otherwise solvent financial institution.

As pointed out by Radelet and Sachs (1998), East Asian financial


institutions had incurred a significant amount of external liquid
liabilities that were not entirely backed by liquid assets, making
them vulnerable to panics. As a result of this maturity
transformation, some otherwise solvent financial institutions may
indeed have been rendered insolvent because they were unable to
deal with the sudden interruption in the international flow of funds.

However, it is apparent that this is not the entire story, as the impact
of the crisis varied significantly across economies. In particular, as
investors tested currency pegs and financial systems in the region,
those economies with the most vulnerable financial sectors
(Indonesia, South Korea, and Thailand) have experienced the most
severe crises. In contrast, economies with more robust and well-
capitalized financial institutions (such as Singapore) have not
experienced similar disruptions, in spite of slowing economic activity
and declining asset values. Indeed the collapse of the Thai baht in
July 1997 and of the Korean won in the last quarter of 1997
were preceded by signs of significant weaknesses in the domestic
financial sector, notably an inability by domestic borrowers to
service their debts. In Indonesia, it became apparent after the crisis
that domestic lenders could not monitor adequately the financial
condition of their borrowers, a situation that worsened the severity
of the crisis. This suggests that understanding what factors
contributed to weaknesses in the financial sectors of the most
affected economies may help make them less vulnerable to
financial crises in the future.

Lack of incentives for risk management

Two characteristics common in countries that have experienced


financial crises were present in a number of East Asian economies.
First, financial intermediaries were not always free to use business
criteria in allocating credit. In some cases, well-connected
borrowers could not be refused credit; in others, poorly managed
firms could obtain loans to meet some government policy objective.
Hindsight reveals that the cumulative effect of this type of credit
allocation can produce massive losses.
Second, financial intermediaries or their owners were not expected
to bear the full costs of failure, reducing the incentive to manage
risk effectively. In particular, financial intermediaries were protected
by implicit or explicit government guarantees against losses,
because governments could not bear the costs of large shocks to
the payments system (McKinnon and Pill 1997) or because the
intermediaries were owned by Ministers nephews (Krugman
1998). Krugman points out that such guarantees can trigger asset
price inflation, reduce economic welfare, and ultimately make the
financial system vulnerable to collapse.

The importance of implicit government guarantees in the most


affected economies is highlighted by the generous support given to
financial institutions experiencing difficulties. For example, in South
Korea, the very high overall debt ratios of corporate conglomerates
(400% or higher) suggest that these borrowers were ultimately
counting on government support in case of adverse outcomes. This
was confirmed by events in 1997, when the government
encouraged banks to extend emergency loans to some troubled
conglomerates which were having difficulties servicing their debts
and supplied special loans to weak banks. These responses further
weakened the financial position of lenders and contributed to the
uncertainty that triggered the financial crisis towards the end of
1997.

Why a crisis now?

Since weaknesses in East Asian financial systems had existed for


decades and were not unique to the region, why did Asia not
experience crises of this magnitude before? Two explanations are
likely. First, rapid growth disguised the extent of risky lending. For
many years, such growth allowed financial policies that shielded
firms that incurred losses from the adverse effects of their
decisions. However, such policies would make economies highly
vulnerable during periods of uncertainty. Second, innovations in
information and transactions technologies have linked these
countries more closely to world financial markets in the 1990s, thus
increasing their vulnerability to changes in market sentiment.

Closer integration with world financial markets adds dimensions of


vulnerability that are not present in a closed economy. In a closed
economy, bad loans caused by risky lending may not lead to a run
because depositors know that the government can supply enough
liquidity to financial institutions to prevent any losses to depositors.
In an open economy, that same injection of liquidity can destabilize
the exchange rate. As a result, during periods of uncertainty, runs
or speculative attacks on a currency can be avoided only if the
holders of domestic assets are assured that the government can
meet the demand for foreign currency. Those East Asian
economies where foreign exchange reserves were large relative to
their short-term borrowing (Philippines, Malaysia, and Taiwan) were
in a better position to provide such assurances than those
economies where such reserves were relatively low (South Korea,
Indonesia, and Thailand). (Singapore and Hong Kong are excluded
from this comparison because their role as offshore financial
centers clouds interpretation of the data.)

Financial sector vulnerability was accentuated by a tendency not to


hedge foreign currency borrowing in countries with pegged
exchange rates. Market participants may have interpreted currency
pegs as implicit government guarantees against the risk of currency
volatility (Dooley 1997), backed by foreign reserves that would be
made available through central bank currency intervention. While
the absence of hedging significantly lowered the cost of funds (in
the short run) for those firms with access to foreign credit, the
consequent mispricing of foreign credit contributed to excessive
capital inflows and the vulnerability of borrowers with heavy
exposure to foreign currency loans.

The lack of hedging also added to the instability in Asian financial


markets once the crisis hit. The high cost of abandoning currency
pegs induced policymakers to adopt harsh contractionary measures
(involving skyrocketing interest rates) to defend the exchange rate,
even when the pegs were unsustainable in the face of adverse
market sentiment. The efforts of market participants to cover
previously unhedged foreign currency exposure after the onset of
the crisis further weakened Asian currencies. After the pegs
collapsed, borrowers who had not hedged their foreign currency
borrowing had difficulty servicing their debts and, in some cases,
went bankrupt, thus worsening the crisis.

Conclusion
A review of East Asias experience suggests that while a classic
panic may have played a role, financial sector weaknesses were a
major contributor to the recent financial crisis. Such weaknesses
appear to reflect the inability of lenders to use business criteria in
allocating credit and implicit or explicit government guarantees
against risk. This implies that it would be prudent to accompany
efforts to spur recovery in East Asia by reforms designed to
strengthen the financial system.

Ramon Moreno
Senior Economist

References
MORE: https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/1997_Asian_financial_crisis

Popular enthusiasm about Asia's boom deserves to have some cold water thrown on
it." - Paul Krugman, The Myth of Asia's Miracle, 1994

The Asian Financial Crisis of 1997 was a financial crisis that affected many Asian
countries, including South Korea, Thailand, Malaysia, Indonesia, Singapore and
the Philippines. After posting some of the most impressive growth rates in the world
at the time, the so-called "tiger economies" saw their stock markets and currencies lost
about 70% of their value.

In this article, we will take a look at the causes of the Asian financial crisis and the
solutions that ultimately brought about a recovery, as well as some lessons for modern
times.

Causes of the Asian Financial Crisis

The Asian Financial Crisis, like many other financial crises before and after it, began
with a series of asset bubbles. Growth in the region's export economies led to high
levels of foreign direct investment, which in turn led to soaring real estate values,
bolder corporate spending, and even large public infrastructure projects - all funded
largely by heavy borrowing from banks.

Of course, ready investors and easy lending often lead to reduced investment quality
and excess capacity soon began to show in these economies. The United States
Federal Reserve also began to raise its interest rates around this time to counteract
inflation, which led to less attractive exports (for those with currencies pegged to the
dollar) and less foreign investment.
The tipping point was the realization by Thailand's investors that its property market
was unsustainable, which was confirmed by Somprasong Land's default and Finance
One's bankruptcy in early 1997. After that, currency traders began attacking the Thai
baht's peg to the U.S. dollar, which proved successful and the currency was eventually
floated and devalued.

Following this devaluation, other Asian currencies including the Malaysian ringgit,
Indonesian rupiah and Singapore dollar all moved sharply lower. These devaluations
led to high inflation and a host of problems that spread as wide as South Korea and
Japan.

Solutions to the Asian Financial Crisis

The Asian Financial Crisis was ultimately solved by the International Monetary Fund
(IMF), which provided the loans necessary to stabilize the troubled Asian economies.
In late 1997, the organization had committed over $110 billion in short-term loans to
Thailand, Indonesia and South Korea to help stabilize the economies - more than
double its largest loan earlier.

In exchange for the funding, the IMF required the countries to adhere to strict
conditions, including higher taxes, reduced public spending, privatization of state-
owned businesses and higher interest rates designed to cool the overheated economies.
Some other restrictions required countries to close illiquid financial institutions
without concern for employment.

By 1999, many of the countries affected by the Asian Financial Crisis showed signs of
recovery with gross domestic product (GDP) growth resuming. Many of the countries
saw their stock markets and currency valuations dramatically reduced from pre-1997
levels, but the solutions imposed set the stage for the re-emergence of Asia as a strong
investment destination.

Lessons of the Asian Financial Crisis

The Asian Financial Crisis has many important lessons that are applicable to events
happening today and events likely to occur in the future.

Here are some important takeaways:

Watch Government Spending - Government dictated spending on public


infrastructure projects and guidance of private capital into certain industries
contributed to asset bubbles that may have been responsible for the crisis.
Re-Evaluate Fixed Exchange Rates - Fixed exchange rates have largely
disappeared, except for instance where they use a basket of currencies, since
flexibility may be needed in many cases in order to avert crisis like these.
Concerns about the IMF - The IMF took a lot of criticism after the crisis for
being too strict in its loan agreements, particularly with successful economies
like South Korea. Moreover, the moral hazard created by the IMF may be a
cause of the crisis.

Always Beware of Asset Bubbles - Investors should carefully watch out for
asset bubbles in the latest/hottest economies around the world. All too often,
these bubbles end up popping and investors are caught off-guard.

The Bottom Line


The Asian financial crisis began with a series of asset bubbles that were financed with
foreign direct investment. When the Federal Reserve began to hike interest rates,
foreign investment dried up and high asset valuations were difficult to sustain. Equity
markets moved significantly lower and the International Monetary Fund eventually
stepped in with billions of dollars worth of loans to stabilize the market. The
economies eventually recovered, but many experts have been critical of the IMF for
its strict policies that may have exacerbated the problems.
A Good Look at the Thai Financial Crisis in 1997-98

1.Introduction

An open economy is susceptible to a speculative attack; the smaller the


economy, the more severely it is likely to get hurt. Good balances in economic
components are the only immunity as well as medicine to such an attack. In 1992,
the European Monetary System had to be practically abolished as its member
economies had been consistently hit by speculators who had seen a way to exploit
economic imbalances that made possible a devaluation of the economies currency.
Two years later, Mexico had encountered calamitous, speculative attacks that had
forced it to devalue the peso by more than 50%. Mexican banking and private
sectors all got hurt and the economy had stopped growing for more than half a
decade. On the other hand, only the central banks of the European economies had
forfeited currency in their foreign reserve in order to promptly stop the crisis.
Thailand was another open economy loudly hit by speculative attacks. It had
enjoyed too much and too recklessly wealth in its good days, the habit which had
given rise to serious imbalances of a number of the economys components. The
overoptimistic characteristic of the economy had essentially led to the deterioration
of its health. With the weak body, not for a long time could it stand against outside
attacks from speculators. Being depleted of its foreign currency reserve in
attempts to fight against the speculative forces, on July 2, 1997, Thailand decided
to switch to a flexible exchange rate regime. The Thai bath was depreciated by
more than 50% by the end of that year; the Thais had experienced a collapse of
their economy for the first time.

This paper was aimed to give a clear picture of the Thai financial crisis and
insight thoughts on some of the issues related. The paper was divided as follow:
Section( 1) Introduction, Section( 2) An Anatomy of the Thai Financial Crisis,
Section (3) Did the Thais Ignore the Painful Lessons of the Mexico?, Section(4)
An Evaluation of the Thai Government Performance along Thailands Economic
Path and in Response to the Crisis, (5) Final Remarks on the Future of the Thai
Economy, Section (6) Conclusion.

2. An Anatomy of the Thai Financial Crisis

Since early 1990s, Thai economy had attracted massive volumes of capital
inflow from aboard due to its accommodating economic policies, goal, healthy-
looking conditions, and some other outside factors such as the stagflation of
Japanese economy and the recession in European countries during 1990s. After a
long period of strict financial regulations that limited credit expansion of
commercial banks, starting from the beginning of 1990s, the Thai government had
decided to accommodate a policy of financial market deregulation and capital
account liberalization. Moreover, with an exchange rate fixed to a basket of world
dominant currencies especially US dollars, the Thais had enjoyed a long period of
nominal exchange rate stability as the baht had fluctuated very narrowly between
24.91-25.59 baht per dollar (Table 1), stable price level of 3.3-5.9%, and high
interest rate at around 13.25% before the crisis.

The Thai government also had done a good job in keeping inflation rate
low between 3.36% and 5.7% (Table 2) as well as fiscal balances surpluses (Table
3). Plus the economy had possessed a characteristic of high saving rates situated at
around 33.5% of GDP while its GDP growth had stayed at an impressive level of
8.08-8.94 during 1991-95. As a result, the Thai economy had become very
attractive to international speculators, many of whom had channeled their large
sum of capital out of Japan which had undergone a lengthy period of stagflation
and low interest rate. And by 1995, Thailand had a net capital inflow of US$
14.239 billion, more than one hundred percent increase from its net capital inflow
three years ago.
As a consequence of the huge overflow of capital, domestic investment had
its prime years and the banking sector had expanded very rapidly. Thailands
investment rate between 1990-96 as shown in Table 4 came in the first place
compared to the other nations of the same region. Stock market prices rose by
175% in aggregate and by 395% in property sector. There emerged more than 50
banks and non-banks financial institutions which had been controlled and
monitored much leniently by the Thai central bankthe Bank of Thailand. These
financial institutions had made a large sum of money out of the economy as they
had had small constraints and difficulties in borrowing quite excessively from
abroad and lending with a dear interest at home. By early 1990s, Thailands banks
were ranked among the worlds most profitable as the banks could charge up to 4
percentage points more interest for loans than they paid on deposits, a discrepancy
which was 4 times bigger than the spreads of less than 1 percentage point in the
banking system of many developed economies. And Thailands lending boom
measure calculated from the growth of bank lending as a percentage of GDP ratio
was 58%, the highest in the East Asian group (Table 5).

However, the growth of the capital inflow and the lending practice of the
Thai financial institutions were not very healthy nor wise. A large part of the
capital had been put into non-productive sectors especially real estate. Those
sectors were non-productive because they produced non-tradable goods which
were sold only domestically, resulting in less national volume of exports and thus
weaken the economys balance of trade as well as the capital account. A statistic
showed that 10-35% of bank loans were committed to bricks and mortar. In
addition, only a small portion of the capital inflow could be categorized as foreign
direct investment (FDI)a non-speculative, thus real, type of investment that went
to the build-ups of capital goods, factories, inventories and land. In table 6, the
percentage of contribution of inward FDI to current account financing was
calculated. The proportion of FDI to the Thai economy was low and had decreased
over time from 33.57% in 1990 to 15.90% in 1996, compared to that of Malaysia
who had a proportion of FDI above 90% throughout the time period. In addition,
the financial institutions tended to lend recklessly without a prudent procedure of
lending contraction and monitoring. This was an adverse selection problem
resulted from moral hazard on the side of the financial institutions as the
institutions had expected a safety net provided by the Thai government or the Bank
of Thailand if a bank run occurred. The same problem was also with the foreign
creditors and depositors sides as they credited money to the financial institutions
with little care, having in mind the governments bailout policy. As Jeffrey Sachs
had presented an early analysis of the role of excessive lending driven by moral
hazard incentives:

Banks and near-bankssuch as Thailands now notorious financial


trustsbecome intermediaries for channeling foreign capital into domestic
economy. The trouble is that the newly liberalized banks and near-banks
often operate under highly distorted incentives. Under-capitalized banks
have incentive to borrow aboard and invest domestically with reckless
abandon. If the lending works out, the bankers make money. If the lending
fails, the depositors and the creditors stand to lose money, but the banks
owners bear little risk themselves because they have little capital tied up in
the bank. Even the depositors and the foreign creditors may be secure from
risk, if the government bails them out in the case of bank failure.[1]

Furthermore, it was worth noted that the lending boom was significantly larger for
finance and securities companies than for banks (133% of the former as opposed to
51% of the latter). And the non-bank share of lending to the private sector was
quite significant (about 33% of bank lending). As a result, Thailand was the only
country, among the countries affected by the Asian crisis, where lending to private
sector was very different if we added the other banking and non-bank financial
institutions figures. Unfortunately, these non-bank institutions tended to have a
very bad lending practice. As later on, they were severely affected by the incident
of non-performing loans crisis, and 56 of them were forced to close their business
in a governments attempt to remedy the crisis which had gone much worse after
the devaluation of the baht. Another imprudent lending practice of the financial
institutions was that they lent from foreigners mostly in dollar denomination and
thus needed to pay back in the foreign-nominated currency, but they relent that
foreign-denominated currency in baht at home. A ratio of foreign liabilities to
assets is shown in table 8. Strikingly, the ratio is far higher in the case of Thailand
than that of the other countries: the ratio of Thailand before the crisis had been
increasing from 6.93 in 1993 to 11.03 in 1996 whereas that of the other countries
never exceeded 4.3 in the same time period. This suggested a serious mismatch
between the stock of foreign liabilities and assets. The Thais would get into a really
big trouble if they needed to repay those liabilities in all of a sudden. This later on
would be shown to be a crucial cause of the deterioration of the nations balance of
payment and the collapse of the economy.

Unfortunately, the golden years did not last long. Starting from the year
1995, Thailands economic growth became much slow down due to a number of
factors such as the contraction in the real estate sector, the emergence of China as
an intimidating competitor in international trade, the fall of world demand of
semiconductor which was one of the Thai major exports in 1996, and an
appreciation of the dollars after Spring 1995. As previously discussed, real estates
were non-tradable; thus, there was a constraint in market demand of them. Too
many houses and business buildings were built; by 1997, the commercial vacancy
rate had gone up to 15% (Table7). The real estate business had become
unprofitable., and the business owners, thus, had no capacity to pay back their
debts to financial institutions when the maturity came. The percentage of non-
performing loans had risen up to 13% in 1996. This soar of the non-performing
loans began the era of banking crisis as banks balance sheet had been deteriorated.
Besides, in international trade, Thailand had become less competitive in the
existence of an emerging trader like China together with a constantly increasing
trend of dollar currency (i.e. an appreciation of dollar) which had worsened
Thailands terms of trade since the Spring of 1995. (The exchange rate of yen for
dollar went from 80 in Spring 1995 to over 125 yen per dollar in Summer 1997).
Thailands terms of trade had been worsened because the Thai baht needed to
appreciate along with the dollar which was the major currency in the currencies
basket Thailand had fixed its exchange rate to. And as the world demand of
semiconductor had fallen in 1996, Thailands volume of exports decreased,
contributing to a balance of trade deficit.

Another item should be looked at was the countrys current account


balance. Thailand had had persistent current account deficit ranging from -5.08 to
-8.10 % of GDP lowest among the other nations for most of the time in the sample
(table9). This negative sum largely came from the countrys balance of trade
deficit. The value of its imports had widely exceeded its export value (table10).
This high volume of imports could be expected as the country had had a high GDP
growth rate (table11). However, the number could look better if Thai people had
been more prudent in spending and could be more competitive exporters. During
the boom period, the economy was in a bubble. Thai people had had an expectation
of a long run economic growth of their country; thus, their consumption had
become quite excessive especially in imported commodities and luxuries.

There came speculators who had seen Thailands slow growth rate, bank
run, and deteriorating balance of payments as signs of unprofitability for their
investment. They started selling domestic assets and claimed back their foreign
assets. As a result, bank balance sheets became increasingly deteriorated, and the
economy had faced a severe credit crunch problem. Even investors with productive
investment opportunities could not get loans to run their business. The countrys
economic growth, thus, had been even more deterred. On February 5, 1997,
Somprasong was the first Thai company to miss the repayment of its foreign
debt. The situation had gone much severe that a large number of Thai financial
institutions were not anymore to pay back their debts; the governments bailout
operation was expected. On March 10, 1997, the Thai government announced that
it would buy $3.9 billion in bad property debt from a number of; however, it
reneged the promise at the end. On May 23 the government made an attempt to
save Finance One, Thailands largest finance company, via a merger with
another financial institution. But again it could not fulfill its mission. As only one
month later, the new finance minister discovered that the Bank of Thailand had
already used US$ 28 billion out of US$ 30 billion of its international reserves in
the course of forward market interventions to defend the value of the baht.

Under a fixed exchange rate system, it was the responsibility of the


government or the central bank to conduct policies i.e. exchange-rate changing,
exchange-rate switching, and direct control, to keep its exchange rate fixed as well
as to maintain a fine level of the overall condition of the economy. An exchange-
rate changing policy was the first approach, constituted of a fiscal and monetary
policy. As more and more capital flew out of the country or as the country had
faced a balance of payments deficit the central bank needed to forfeit its foreign
reserves, injecting the foreign currency into the economy to satisfy the currencys
excess demand and bring the economy back to its exchange rate equilibrium. So as
speculators had kept taking dollars out of the system (i.e. Thai economy) , the
Bank of Thailand had a necessity to inject dollars into the system using its stock of
foreign reserves. Not for a long time, however, did the central bank could do that.
Its stock of foreign reserves was almost used up, and it realized that it could not, in
any way, be able to supply the foreign currency to the economy given the
enormous size of foreign liabilities. (This, you can look back in table 8.) An
exchange-rate switching policy, thus, soon would need to be committed. The
speculators knew the situation as well and had realized a mammoth gain from a
devalued baht as their foreign assets would worth much more. So there occurred
the first massive speculative attack in the Thai history on May 14-15, 1997. Only
in Spring of 1997, more than 90% of the countrys foreign reserve had been used
to defend the value of the baht, and the country was forced to finally switch its
exchange rate regime. On July 2, 1997, Thailand had become under a flexible
exchange rate system; the Thai baht was devalued by about 15-20 percent (28.80
baht per dollar) after the announcement. The value of the baht had continuously
gone down since then and reached the bottom at 48.80 baht per dollar in December
of the same year, the highest rate (lowest value of the Thai baht) ever since
Thailand started keeping record in 1969.

In this world, open economies were interrelated basically through trade and
capital flow, and the health of an economy essentially depended upon how well the
economy had managed itself to be in a healthy balance of trade and capital flow. If
the balances could not be obtained, the economy became unstable and, sooner or
later, it would fall down. It might get injured seriously or not seriously dependent
on its remaining strength and how and where it fell down. The Thai economy had
not well managed its balances. It was too reckless in capital flow management
which resulted in an imbalance of bank balance sheets of the nations financial
institutions. In trade, however, an imbalance was largely caused by outside factors
which were likely to be exogenous to the Thai economy, for instance, the
emergence of China in international trade, the appreciation of the dollars, and the
fall of world demand of semiconductor. The Thais might be able to do things such
as the abandonment of an exchange rate regime that caused the Thai baht to move
in the same direction as that of the dollars, and investment in research and
development to find other types of exports that Thailand could profitably produce
and export.
3. Do the Thais Ignore the Painful Lessons of Mexico?

The Thai financial crisis appeared to be very similar to the Mexican


financial crisis of 1994-95. In both cases, an enormous amount of capital was
injected into the economies, of which a large part was speculative. The capital had
caused overlending syndrome of financial institutions that were loosely monitored
by the central bank. The central bank, on the other hand, promised to bailout
financial institutions that failed in operation, a policy which had created moral
hazard in the financial institutions as well as the creditors and depositors. Then,
good years had passed; the economies had experienced slow economic growth and
capital outflow. The outflow of capital had caused a bank run which
later developed to be a banking crisis. And the necessity of the central bank to get
the economy going by supplying foreign currency out of its reserves had been
proved to be too huge a task that the central bank finally had to commit to an
exchange-rate switching policy, and the economies had to suffer a long period of
recession afterwards.

(Points of argument which would follow were products of an attempt to


understand and explain some of the behaviors of the economy. The points were
only suggestive, not necessarily true. Plus, the points were essentially based on
psychological aspects of the issue, and, thus, should be considered together with
tangible aspects which were believed to be more rational. For example, as the
reader realized that Thailand had believed that it would be after Japan not Mexico,
the reader should also have in mind the fact that the Thais had not felt carefree as
they must have seen their countrys statistics, for example, persistent current
account deficits, problematically mismatching ratio of foreign liabilities to foreign
assets, which indicated a fragile condition of the country.)

So do the Thais forget the painful lessons of Mexico? I would say yes, but
without many choices. By the time that Mexico had entered into the financial
crisis (1994-95), the Thai economy had begun to get used to a new style of
economic liberalization. Thai people had earned more income and had become
more and more proud of the growth of their economy. A set of government who
came in and suddenly made the economy less appreciable would become
unpopular. Thus, the governments in power during that period had preferred not to
change the picture of the economy much. So, political concerns did have impacts
on the direction of the economic policies. Besides, the Thai economy had had one
characteristic much contributing to the rationale of the economy along its path. It
believed in a miracle, and that it could make things different. As commented by
Paul Krugman:

Well, maybe the revelation that Asian nations do, in fact, live in the same
economic universe as the rest of us will provoke some much-needed
reflection on the realities of the Asian economic miracle.[2]

The Asian countries were believed to have Japan as a model for their economic
development. After World War II, Japan could quickly and profitably expand its
economy especially its manufacturing sector, and became the second largest
economy of the world in only less than four decades afterwards. It started from
exporting low-technical goods such as watches and electronic appliances. Only
shortly afterward, it shifted to produce merchandises which required higher level
of technology, for example, automobiles, computers. Then, it moved on to cross-
border investment, and not long afterwards, it became the biggest creditor of the
world. The Asian countries had observed the success of Japanese economy and
believed that they, as well, could do the same thing. Thailand, for example, had
started with producing and exporting electronic and automobile parts, then moved
on to real estate investment, and planned to do good at capital investment. In less
than a decade, the country had grown so much that it believed that it had been on a
right path, a path which would lead it to the prosperity that Japan had enjoyed.
Investment boom and the rise of cities were evident in the path of the growth. Ten
years ago, if you traveled along Chao-Pra-Ya river, a main river in Bangkok, you
would see only vast rice fields along both sides of the river. Today, however, the
rice fields had turned to be tall business buildings, hotels, and restaurants. This sort
of phenomenon also happened to some other provinces in Thailand which had
grown to be cities as the economy had expanded so much that Bangkok could not
alone accommodate all the businesses and industries. And in 1994-95, Thailand
must observe the economic crisis and collapse of the Mexican economy.
Unfortunately, it probably would have seen itself after Japan and not Mexico.
Miraculously successful as it had seen itself to be, it believed that it would not fall.

4. An Evaluation of the Thai Government Performance along Thailands


Economic Path and in Response to the Crisis.

The Thai governments had not done a very good job. They had not dared to
be far-sighted as they were still concerned much about politics. They had stuck to
the goal held since the first time of capital account liberalization, a goal which had
aimed at the expansion of the economy. The economy did expand, however, not
quite healthily. It was like a bubble, continuously inflated, but the bigger it
became, the more easily it would explode even with a soft touch of a rough
surface.

The liberalization of the financial sector had been proved to be too reckless.
Statistics such as ratio of foreign liabilities to foreign assets, non-performing loans,
contribution of inward FDI to current account financing, had been evidences of the
recklessness. However, even a good statistics like high GDP growth could not have
made the economy joyful. Thailands GDP growth had been high at around 8.5%
during the first half of 1990s. Nevertheless, a large contribution of the growth had
come from production of non-tradable good and from pure speculative capital
inflow. The structure of the Thai economy was still not ready for that large amount
of capital not to be used in real investment. If Thailand had run current account
surplus and balance of trade surplus as high as that of Taiwan or Singapore (table9
and table 10), it might have a reason and want to liberate itself that much in the
financial world.

Politics seemed to be much influential in policy making of the government.


The majority of Thai people who walked on the street had been made to see only a
prosper side of the economy. It had only been shown to them the growing of the
cities and business sectors, and statistics such as high GDP growth, high saving
rate, government fiscal balance surpluses, high volume of exports, a claim that
Thailand had become one of the Asian Tigers. But it had not been shown to them
how serious the country had become indebted, and how recklessly capital had been
transferred and used in the economy. Thai people should be better informed and
made sophisticated. The Thai government had tried to maintain its popularity even
in the last minute when it decided not to ask IMF for a rescue package immediately
after the devaluation of the baht was announced, but waited until 26 days later to
eventually called in the IMF. This delay had a serious consequence as it
exacerbated the situation of bank run. According to Frederic S. Mishkin, it was
believed that the faster the lending was done, the lower was the amount that
actually had to be lent.[3] The action of the government, thus, was highly
disadvantageous to the economy. Whereas the US Federal Reserve Bank could
engage in a lender of last resort operation in a day in the event of stock market
crash of 1987, the Bank of Thailand had postponed for another 26 days before it
engaged in a lending operation.

Another government conduct worth to be discussed was its loose monetary


policy during the period right after the first devaluation of the baht. Committing to
that policy, the government showed its steadfast attempt to promote the production
and thus the growth of the economy, an objective which had never been set aside.
It had kept interest rate low so that the amount of money supply in the economy
would be high which would encourage domestic consumption and investment. This
conformed to the Laffer curve condition saying that a fall not a rise of interest
rate would have strengthen the economy and restored confidence. Unfortunately,
the problem of bank panic was so serious that no matter how much money supply
the economy had, the creditors would attempt their best to take money out of the
system and did not invest. This resulted in a continuous spiral of currency
depreciation that dramatically increased the real burden of the foreign-currency
liabilities. Seeing that a loose monetary did not work, the government later on had
switched to tighten its monetary policy. It raised domestic interest rate, hoping to
retain money in the system. However, the policy turned out to be propelling a more
serious contraction of the Thai economy and credit crunch.

5. Final Remarks on the Future of the Thai Economy.

The Thai financial crisis was built upon macroeconomic imbalances of the
country, and those imbalances were essentially attributable to the faulty structure
of the nations financial sector. A financial restructuring thus became the first
episode of its road to discovery. Beside that it would be ensured that a similar type
of financial crisis would not happen again in the future, the financial restructuring
would have an immediate or short term benefit to the economy as it would beef up
the investors confidence to bring in credits or capital into the Thai economy in
order to make the economy move again.

The next step was that Thailand needed to try to have a reliable and capable
institution which could give it a safety net when such a crisis occurred. Unlike the
Fed, the Bank of Thailand had a constraint on its foreign-currency reserves which
were to be used to pay the nations debt. So the Bank of Thailand, at least in this
ten or fifteen years, would not be able to function as a lender-of-last-resort. This
job, therefore, needed to be given to a powerful international institution like IMF.
The Bank of Thailand, however, should be reconstructed so that it became
independent to the government in its policy making since politics was proved to be
a crucial source of the unhealthiness of the economy.

Beside a strong financial structure and a good supporting institution in case


of a future financial crisis, from this point on, Thailand needed to be careful in
keeping things in a well order. For instance, current account deficit should not be
much in excess of 5% of GDP especially if the deficit was financed in a way that
could lead to rapid reversals according to the US Deputy Treasury Secretary
Lawrence Summers[4]; Banks should be restricted in how fast their borrowing
could grow (Mishkin)[5].

6. Conclusion

To achieve Macroeconomic balances, great care and prudent policy


management are needed. To be prudent was to be far-sighted and realistic. In the
Thai financial crisis case, policies had not been prudently thought out. The collapse
of the economy was a very tough lesson for the Thais. It would take long for the
economy to recover. (It was predicted to be longer than that of Mexico concisely
because the other countries of the region were also hit. Thus, Thailand could not
gain much terms of trade after the devaluation of the baht to help improving its
economy. Plus, the slow down of Japanese economy had made it unable to give
much aid to Thailand unlike Mexico who had a huge support from the US for the
road to its recovery.) But hopefully, during that long road, the Thais would
maximally utilize the time to thought out wise policies and beef up a real strength
so that when the next storm came, it would not turn over again.

You might also like