You are on page 1of 19

Compulsory Pooling and Unitization: State Options

in Dealing with Uncooperative Owners


Bruce M. Kramer*

1. INTRODUCTION-THE HISTORICAL CONTEXT

The oil and gas industry has often been compared with other forms
of games of chance as, for example, the stock market or the craps
table. You can either make it big or take a beating on your invested
capital. The following hypothetical situation and the attempts by
states to deal with it in their compulsory pooling and unitization'
statutes, illustrate the high risk nature of the business.
Assume that a stock broker or professional gambler approached
you with the following offer: the broker/gambler will advance you
$3000 or $3,000,000 if you agree to invest it at her request. She agrees
to bear the entire risk of loss should the stock decline or craps be
rolled at the gaming table. If the return on the investment is less
than $3000 or $3,000,000 you owe her nothing. If, however, the return
on the investment exceeds either of those sums, all profit is turned
over to you while she keeps only the initial investment advanced to
you. This is an offer one could truly not refuse. While nO rational
gambler or stock broker would ever make this offer, an analogous sit-
uation arises in the oil and gas industry when operators seeking to
develop their mineral holdings are unable to have unleased mineral
owners or other working interest owners voluntarily agree to pool or
unitize their interests. In the absence of a compulsory pooling or uni-
tization mechanism," if the operator wanted to develop his interest,

* Professor of Law, Texas Tech University School of Law, Lubbock, Texas. B.A. 1968, Uni-
versity of California, Los Angeles; J.D. 1972, University of California, Los Angeles School of
Law; LL.M. 1975, University of Illinois College of Law.
I Pooling and unitization are analogous but not identical concepts. Pooling usually describes

the joining together of tracts in order to receive a drilling permit under the applicable well
spacing rule for the area. Unitization- refers to the joining together of tracts in order to coopera~
tively develop all or _part of a reservoir containing hydrocarbons. Unitization is sometimes re-
ferred to as a unit operation. See 8 H. Wn.LIAMS & C. MEYERS, OJL AND GAS LAW 652, 938-39
(1984). For the purposes of this paper the terms are interchangeable since we will be analyzing
the impact of compulsory pooling or unitization on the unleased mineral owner or,the uncoop-
erative working interest owner. The fact that the compulsory procedure is part of a unitization
order or a pooling order will not drastically affect the results.
= Most of the major oil and gas producing states have statutory procedures relating to COln-
pulsory pooling and unitization. For a complete list of all of those states. see 2 & 3 R. MEYERS,

255
256 JOURNAL OF ENERGY LAW AND POLICY [Vol. 7 1986] POOLING AND UNITIZATION 257
the unleased or uncooperative owner would be in the same position Interposed with these common-law rules, including the rule of cap-
as the fortuitous gambler or investor in the hypothetical situation. ture, 7 are complex regulations passed pursuant to state police power.
This article will explore how states deal with this result which, on its These regulations have been enacted by the states since the early
face, discourages voluntary agreements to pool or unitize, and there- 1920's in order to conserve and prevent waste of oil and gas re-
fore discourages conservation of resources and efficiency goals in the sources. Before the regulatory era began, the owners of mineral inter-
allocation of capital investment in the oil and gas industry. ests were free to exploit oil and gas with little or no constraints." This
The reason why an operator might have to "carry" the unleased or exploitation led to tremendous over-drilling because of the economic
uncooperative owner has its basis in the way that the common law realities of the rule of capture." One regulatory method used to con-
treats cotenancy interests in oil and gas. Each cotenant of the min-
eral estate had the right to drill for and produce hydrocarbons with- 612 (196S):
out the consent of the other cotenants! Because the drilling cotenant Anyone of these owners individually could have entered upon section 31 and ex-
plored for oil and gas. (Callahan v. Martin, supra, 3 Cal. 2d 110, 125-126, 43 P.2d 788
is in effect taking part of the undivided minerals owned by the other (1935)). In doing so, however, he would, if unsuccessful, have been compelled to bear
cotenant, the common-law rule requires that the drilling cotenant the entire expense and risk of the operations. (See Little v. Mountain View Dairies
provide an accounting to the other cotenant for his pro rata share of (1950) 35 Cal. 2d 232, 234. 217 l'.2d 416; cf. McCord v. Oakland Q.M. CO. (lS83) 64
the oil and gas produced.' The drilling cotenant, however, is entitled Cal. 134, 149-150, 27 P. 863.) If he had succeeded in his endeavor, he could not have
exch,lded from section 31 other cotenants who had desired to drill (Dabney-Johnston
to deduct the non-drilling cotenant's pro rata share of the reasonable Oil Corp. v. Walden, supra, 4 Cal. 2d 637, 655, 52 P.2d 237; Callahan v. Martin,
costs of development, production and marketing,' If the well is dry or supra, 3 Cal. 2d 110, 125~126, 43 P.2d 788), and, as to the remaining cotenants, he
never recovers sufficient revenue to pay the costs of development, the would have been required to render an accounting for the profits (Dabney-Johnston
Oil Corp. v. WaJden. supra, 4 Cal. 2d 637, 655-657, 52 P.2d 237) (footnote omitted).
drilling cotenant sustains the entire loss. Under the common law, a Id. at 894, 442 P.2d at 716, 69 Cal. Rptr. at 636; see also P & N Inv. Corp. v. Florida Ranchet-
non-consenting working interest owner or an unleased cotenant can- tes, Inc., 220 So.2d 451, 453-54 (Fla. Dist. Ct. App. 1969); Krug v. Krug, 5 Kan. App. 2d 426,
not be forced to share the risk of a dry or marginally productive 618 P.2d 323, 325-26 (1980).
7 Professor Hardwicke has defined the rule of capture as it applies to oil and gas as follows:
well." "The owner of a tract of land acquires title to the oil or gas whic;h he produces from wells
drilled thereon, though it may be proved that part of such oil or gas migrated from adjoining
lands." Hardwicke, The Rule of Capture and Its Implications as Applied to Oil and Gas, 13
THE LAW OF POOLING AND UNITIZATION (1985). The only exceptions are Kansas, which has no TEX. L. REV. 391, 393 (1935); see also 5 E. KUNTZ, LAW OF OIL AND GAS § 77.1 (1978).
ct. J.
compulsory pooling statute and Texas, which has no compulsory unitization statute. But 8 Under the classic definition the owner of the mineral estate has an absolute right to drill as
WEAVER, UNITIZATION OF OIL AND GAS FIELDS IN TEXAS: A STUDY OF LEGISLATIVE, ADMINISTRA-
many wells OIl his land as his pocket book and fancy will allow. Breaux v. Pan Am. Petroleum
TIVE AND JUDICIAL POLICIES (1986) (analysis of how Texas Railroad Commission achieved de Corp., 163 So.2d 406, 415 (La. Ct. App. 1964), writ re{'d. 246 L.. 5S1. 165 So.2d 481 (1964).
facto compulsory unitization in absence of de jure compulsory unitization statute). Professor Kuntz summarized the impact of the rule of capture on the overdriIling of wells as
8 See, e.g., Prairie Oil & Gas Co. v. Allen, 2 F.2d 566, 571 (8th Cir. 1924); Texas & Pac. Coal
follows:
& Oil Co. v. Kirtley,288 S.W. 61!;}, 623 (Tex. Civ. App. 1926). See generally Williams, The The consequences of the law of capture which made it necessary to regulate the pro~
Effect of Concurrent Interests on Oil and Gas Transactions, 34 TEx. L. REv. 519, 520 (1956). A duction of oil also made it necessary to regulate the density of drilling. Under the law
number of states do not follow the majority rule that each cotenant has the right to drill for of capture, each landowner has the right to extract oil and gas from beneath his land
hydrocarbons, using as their rationale the common law doctrine of waste. TIlinois, West Virginia without violating the rights of another even though the oil or gas so produced is
and Louisiana, before their most recent changes in the Mineral Code, allowed one cotenant to drained from b~neath the land of another. Fllrther, subject to the correlative rights of
enjoin another cotenant's attempt to remove oil and gas from the ground. Zeigler v. Brenne- others, each owner may drill as many wells on his land as he chooses. To avoid the
man, 237 Ill. 15, 23-25. 86 N.R. 597. 600-01 (190S); Gulf Ref. Co. v. Carroll. 145 La. 299, 303- loss of oil or gas by drainage, each owner is inclined to drill all of the wells which he
304. 82 So. 277, 279-S0 (1919); Ree Corp. v. Sheffer. 246 So.2d 313, 320 (La. Ct. App. 1971). can economically drill in order to produce as much oil or gas as possible and to pro-
aff'd, 261 La. 502, 260 So.2d 307 (1972); South Penn Oil Co. v. Aught. 71 W. Va. 720, 72S, 78 duce it as quickly as possible.
S.E. 759, 762 (1913). The changes in LA. REV. STAT. ANN. §§ 31:175-76 (West 1975) are discussed S E. KUNTZ, supra note 7, § 77.1, at 390 (footnote omitted).
in GMB Gas Corp. v. Cox, 340 So.2d 63S. 640-41 (La. Ct. App. 1976). 9 It is estimated that in the East Texas field over 17,000 wells were drilled while only 1500
« See Prairie Oil & Gas Co. v. Allen, 2 F.2d 566, 574' (8th Cir. 1924); Gerhardv. Stephens, 68 would have adequately drained the reservoir underlying'the largest oil and gas field in the
Cal. 2d 864, 894, 442 P.2d 692, 716, 69 Cal. Rptr. 612, 636 (1968); Prewett v. Van Pelt. lIS Kan. continental United States. W. LOVEJOY & P. HOMAN, ECONOMIC ASPECTS OF OIL CONSERVATION
571, 574-76, 235 P. 1059. 1060-61 (1925); White v. Smyth. 147 Tex. 272, 2S5, 214 S.W.2d 967. REGULATION 121 (1967); see also J. WEAVER, supra note 2; McDONALD, PETROLEUM CONSERVA-
975 (194S). TION IN THE UNITED STATES: AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS (1971). Professor Hardwicke estimated that
Ii See cases cited supra note 4. in the period 1947-1952 the amount spent on the drilling of unneeded wells was in the range of
6 The California Supreme Court succinctly summarized the right of a cotenant to drill and $100 million, at a time when oil was selling for $1.00 or $2.00 a barrel. Hardwicke, Oil- Well
then render an accounting in Gerhard v. Stephens, 68 Cal. 2d 864, 442 P.2d 692, 69 Cal. Rptr. Spacing Regulations and Protection of Property Rights in Texas, 31 TEx. L. REV. 99, 111 &
258 JOURNAL OF ENERGY LAW AND POLICY [Vol. 7 1986) POOLING AND UNITIZATION 259

trol this waste of natural resources was the enactment of compulsory been adopted in almost every state which produces oil and gas, '5 al-
pooling and unitization statutes.'o though in the tradition of Brandeis' aphorism of the states as fifty
The concepts of well spacing and pooling go hand in hand. Without grand experiments, there are substantial differences between the
well spacing regulation, if only one well were to be drilled on a forty states in their approach to the problem.'·
acre tract in which multiple interests existed, disputes would cer- The function of the compulsory pooling or unitization process
tainly arise as to which mineral owner or mineral lessee would be should be to remedy the weaknesses of the marketplace while achiev-
entitled to that single well. If the well spacing provisions were fixed , ing the public objectives of preventing waste, conserving oil and gas,
the economic necessities of the circumstances would force the owners and protecting correlative rights. Because of the impact of the rule of
of the mineral or working interests to reach a private accommodation capture and the geologic quality of the movement of oil and gas to
in order to drill their one well." Unfortunately, as the Texas experi- areas of lower pressure, the marketplace may not operate as the ideal
ence illustrates, well spacing regulations were rife with exceptions; mechanism for the allocation of this scarce resource. The best way to
governing policy normally allowed the drilling of more wells than was determine how the marketplace would operate is to see how volun-
otherwise needed in order to efficiently and effectively drain the • tary pooling and unitization agreements deal with the problem of
reservoir.12 non-consenting working interest owners who choose not to partici-
pate in the drilling of the unit well.
Because the impediments placed in the way of voluntary pooling
Voluntary agreements normally provide one of four different alter-
and unitization agreements by various state regulatory programs and
natives for the non-consenting working interest owner if he does not
the common-law rule of capture, efforts were made to force pool or participate in the drilling program." One option is for the other
unitize oil and gas properties in order to achieve three goals: conserv- working interest owners to buyout the working interest owned by the
ing oil and gas, preventing waste, and protecting correlative rights." non-consenting owner. A second option allows the non-consentor to
As early as 1929, the Section of Mineral Law of the American Bar
Association had developed a model compulsory unit operation statute
in order to force uncooperative mineral and working interest owners 1& See supra note 2.
16 For example Texas, which does not have a compulsory unitization statute, requires that an
to join in cooperative development and operation of the oil and gas operator Who wishes to use the compulsory pooling process must make a "fait and reasonable
pool." Since then, compulsory pooling and unitization statutes have offer to pool voluntarily" before the Railroad Commission has jurisdiction to entertain the com-
pulsory pooling petition. TEx. NAT. RES. CODE ANN. § 102.013 (Vernon 1978). Oklahoma on the
other hand does not require the applicant for a pooling order to attempt to voluntarily pool
n.27 (1952). The applicant need only file with the Corp<?ration Commission a petition seeking to force pool
10 The other principal methods of oil and gas conservation were: (1) Well Spacing-The reg-
the interests located in a drilling or spacing unit. OKLA. STAT. ANN. tit. '52, § 87.1(e) (West 1984
ulation of the number and location of wells that can be drilled within a specified amount of & Supp. 19S5).
11 6 H. WILLIAMS & C. MEYERS, OIL AND GAS LAW 23·30.3 (1985). The four alternatives offered
acreage; (2) Drilling Operations':-'"The regulation of procedures used in drilling and completing
wells; (3) Maximum Efficient Rate_Limiting productive capabilities to the· maximum efficient by Professors Williams and Meyers are couched in slightly different· terms in Ryan,' Current
rate (MER) of the well based on its geological capabilities; and (4) Prorationing-Limiting the Problems in Federal Unitization, with Particular Reference to Unit Operating Agreements, 2
amount of oil and gas that can be sold from each well within a common source of supply or ROCKY MTN. MIN. L. INST. 157, 171 w75 (1'956). In discussing a model unitization agreement deal·
reservoir and allocating that amount between the various wells that are producing from that ing with federal lands ,the author concluded that there were three main approaches, with one of
common source. R. SULLIVAN, HANDBOOK OF OIL AND GAS LAW 285 (1955). those approaches having two different alternatives. Under the "acreage" plan any non-con-
sentor would be required to assign his interest to the operator for a cash bonus based on the
For a complete history of oil and gas conservation efforts at both the federal and state gov-
fair market value per acre. Id. at 172. This is equivalent to the first option presented by Wil-
ernmentallevel, see AMERICAN BAR ASSOCIATION, CONSERVATION OF OIL AND GAS: A LEGAL HIS-
liams and Meyers. The second option is called the "cash" plan and mirrors the second option
TORY, (B. Murphy ed. 1948); AMERICAN BAR ASSOCIATION, LEGAL HISTORY OF CONSERVATION OF
presented by Williams and Meyers in that the nonwconsentor is given a free ride up until the
OIL AND GAS (1938).
moment a producing well is completed. At that time, the entire amount of his pro rata share or
11 For a general discussion of spacing units, see 5 E.KuNTZ, supra note 7, §§ 77.1w.3, at 391-
share of costs plus a penalty becomes immediately due~ See id. The third option has two sub-
401; R. SULLIVAN, supra note 10, at 297w305. parts in the "production" plan. In the first sub-part the non-consentor's share of production
12 The history of Rule 37 in Texas is summarized in Hardwicke, supra note 9, at 101-05, and
from a producing well is off-set against his pro rata share of costs plus a risk penalty in an
R. SULLIVAN, supra note 10, at 305-30B. accounting transaction. The second sub·part is more formalistic in that the non-consentor for w
13 1 R. MEYERS, THE LAW OF POOLING AND UNITIZATION 256 (1967). mally transfets an interest to the operator with a reverter when the operator recovers the non-
14 Report of the Committee on Conservation of Mineral Resources of the American Bar Asso- consentor's pro rata share of the costs plus a risk penalty. Id. at 173. As can be seen, the means
ciation, 54 REP. A.BA 739, 762-70 (1929). are changed but the descriptions are basically the 'same.
260 JOURNAL OF ENERGY LAW AND POLICY [Vol. 7 1986] POOLING AND UNITIZATION 261
be "carried" for his pro rata share of expenses until a productive well do not make it less palatable but seemingly reward holdouts by offer-
is completed. The share of costs is then immediately due. This option ing more than the marketplace would if a holdout forces the operator
is often accompanied by a penalty, sometimes denoted as a risk pen- to go through the administrative process.
alty, in order to compensate the operator for the risk of drilling a dry
hole.'· A third option allows the non-consentor to be "carried" with- II. THE PROBLEM OF THE NON-CONSENTING WORKING INTEREST
out risk but does not call for immediate payment upon completion of OWNER
a producing well. Instead, the share of costs plus the risk penalty are
recovered out of the non-consentor's allocated share of the produc- To contrast with the four alternatives normally offered in the pri-
tion.'· A fourth option is to require the non-consentor to relinquish vate sector, state compulsory pooling and unitization statutes utilize
to the operator his working interest in the well subject to a future a somewhat different set of four alternatives in order to force a non-
consenting working interest owner to pool or unitize his interests
interest retained by the non-consentor. The future interest becomes
,
with those other operators working to develop the mineral interests.
possessory when the non-consentor's share of the costs plus risk pen-
The first alternative can be labeled the "free ride." The non-con-
alty is paid out of his share of the oil/gas.'·
senting working interest owner is "carried" as to his proportionate
In all but the first alternative, the non-consenting working interest share of expenses without penalty during the time that the weI! is
owner's share of the costs of drilling are "carried" by the other opera- being drilled. If the well is successful" the non-consentor is only liable
tors. The risk penalty concept is utilized in order to compensate the for his share of the costs out of the production actually achieved. If
risk takers for the chances taken by them in drilling a dry hole. In the well is a dry hole, the non-consentor owes nothing.'· The second
the first alternative, there is essentially no lOnger a non-consent prob- option also allows the non-consentor to be "carried" during the drill-
lem because the operator has transferred voluntarily all of his inter- ing period, but it imposes upon him a risk penalty to compensate the
ests to the remaining operators and no longer has a stake in I' drilling parties for the risk of drilling a dry hole. Again, if the well is
production. dry, the non-consentor pays nothing, while if oil is found, the non-
If no voluntary pooling or unitization agreement can be worked out consentor is assessed a risk penalty.'· A third groUP of statutes au-
by the proposed operator, either the non-consenting mineral or the thorizes the governmental body to permit the non-consentor to elect
working interest owner must be "carried" without any liability for or choose one of several options. The options usually given the co-
their share of the expenses of drilling a dry hole. This is the example lessee include accepting a cash bonus in exchange for the transfer of
raised by the opening hypothetical. 21 The economic incentive for the working interest, electing to participate on an uncarried basis by
working interest owners to join in such voluntary agreements is payment of his proportionate share of expenses, or participating on a
thereby diminished unless the proposed operator can resort to a com- carried basis with the imposition of a risk penalty'" The last group of
pulsory process which forces the owner to make choices which are statutes does not address the problem of the non-consenting working
equally or less palatable to such holdouts. Unfortunately, several interest owner. Any power to deal with the non-consentor must be
state approaches to the compulsory pooling and unitization process gleaned from the regulato~y agency's general authority to issue pool-
ing or unitization orders. Practices of administrative agencies, which
18 This option has several disadvantages. The first is defining when a productive well occurs.
have broad discretion, vary from state to state."
Is a marginally productive well which covers operating costs but will never recoup the initial
investment in the drilling costs a productive well? In addition, the transfer of a large lump sum A. "Free Ride" States
might be treated as ordinary income by the operator with negative tax liability consequences.
See Ryan, supra note 17. at 173. Eleven states which have compulsory pooling statutes give the non-
19 See, e.g., Minor v. Pan Am. Petroleum Corp., 216 F. Supp. 86, 88-89 (w.n. La. 1962)
consenting working interest owner a "free ride" in the drilling of a
(agreement enforced imposing 150% risk penalty on non-consentor's share of production
caused by deepening an existing well).
20 This last option may run into problems with the Rule Against Perpetuities. See Kuntz,
22 See infra section lIA.
The Rule Against Perpetuities and Mineral Interests, 8 OKLA. L. REV. 183, 199 (1955). If the 28 See infra section lIB.
grantor's interest is treated as a possibility of reverter, the rule would not apply. 24 See infra section lIC.
21 See supra text accompanying note 1.
n See infra section lID.
262 JOURNAL OF ENERGY LAW AND POLICY [Vol. 7 1986] POOLING AND UNITIZATION 263

well." Although there are three different methods of discerning the unit belonging to each lessee."3. Again the non-consentor is given a
nature of the free ride, the effect is to allow the non-consentor to free ride in that the operator's right of reimbursement only comes
have his share of the cost of the well taken solely out of production. out of actual production. The major distinction between this group
If the well is a dry hole, the non-consentor is not forced to pay any- and the preceding group is the inclusion of a statutory lien on the
thing. The statute in effect requires the operator to give an interest- share of production accruing to the interest of each non-consenting
free loan to the non-consentor. In the absence of substantial produc- owner. Thus, the operator has both the right to reimbursement out of
tion from the well, the loan will be defaulted, with no further re- production and a lien on that production_ The lien is normally mar-
course available to compensate the operator for potential losses. This ketable and may be sold in order to pay the pro rata share of costs
attributable to the individual lessees. 31
is the hypothetical situation which opened the discussion of this
The three remaining free ride states do not even provide the opera-
problem."' tor with a direct entitlement to production. Instead, these states pro-
The first group of free ride states essentially gives the operator the vide for an operator's lien covering the non-consenting owner's share
right to charge his expenditures against the proportionate interests of of production up to the amount owed the operator." In practice,
all of the non-consenting owners. The charge is reimbursed to the however, the results will probably be no different than those states
operator out of the first production from the well."' The non-con- which do provide for a direct entitlement to production.
sentor is treated as a non-drilling cotenant who is entitled to an ac- The problem with all these provisions is that they encourage indi-
counting of expenditures and production, but who receives no actual vidual working interest owners to hold out of voluntary pooling or
money until the operator has recouped his out-of-pocket expenses in unitization agreements. It would not be in the best interest of the
drilling and operating the well. Of these states, only Florida autho- working interest owner to buy into an operating agreement and face
rizes the operator to have a lien on the leasehold estate of each sepa- the dual burden of providing up-front capital for the drilling, and
rately owned tract in order to provide a security interest in the also the risk of losing his entire investment in the event of a dry hole.
amount of production.'· This lien also applies to consenting owners
who are otherwise being carried by the operator. .. ALASKA STAT. § 31.05.100(c) (1979); ARIZ. REV. STAT. ANN. § 27-505(A) (1976); NEV. REV.
Another group of three states provides for "reimbursement of costs STAT. § 522.060(3) (19S3).
chargeable to each lessee out of, and only out of, production from the 31 The Arizona statute is typical. It provides in pertinent part:
If one or more of the owners drills and operates, or pays the expense of drilling and
operating the well for the benefit of others, then, in addition to any other rights con-
ferred by the pooling order, the owner or owners so drilling or operating shall have a
" ALA. CODE § 9-17-13 (1980); ALASKA STAT. § 31.05.100(e) (1979); MIZ. REv. STAT. ANN. § 27-
lien on the share of production from the unit accruing to the interest of each of the
505(A) (1976); FLA. STAT. ANN. § 377.27 (West 1974); IND. CODE ANN. § 13-4-7-14 (Burns 1981);
other owners for the payment of his proportionate share of the expenses. All the oil
IOWA CODE ANN. § 84.8(2) (West 1984); Mo. ANN. STAT. § 259.110 (Vernon Supp. 1985); MONT.
and gas subject to the lien, or so much thereof as necessary, shall be marketed and
CODE ANN. § 82-11-202(2) (1983); NEV. REv. STAT. § 522.060(3) (1983); N.C. GEN. STAT. § 113-393
sold by the creditor and the proceeds applied iJ;J. payment of the expenses secured by
(1983); N.D. CENT. CODE § 38·08-08 (Supp. 1985).
the lien, with the balance if any payable to the debtor.
2'1 See supra text accompanying note 1.
Amz. REV. STAT. ANN. § 27·505(A) (1976).
28 See, e.g., ALA. CODE § 9-17-13 (1980); FLA. STAT. ANN. § 377.27 (West 1974); IND. CODE ANN.
" IOWA CODE ANN. § S4.S(2) (West 19S4); Mo. ANN. STAT. § 259.110 (VernonSupp. 19S5);
§ 13-4-7-14 (Burns 1981); N.C. GEN. STAT. § 113-393 (19S3). N.D. CENT. CODE § 3S-08-0S (Supp. 19S5).
The Alabama provision is typical of this group of statutes. It provides: The North Dakota statute is typical. It provides in pertinent part:
[T]he operator designated by the Board to develop and operate the integrated or If one or more of the owners shall drill and operate, or pay the expenses of drilling
pooled unit shall have the right to charge against the interest of each other owner in and operating the well for the benefit of others, then, the owner or owners so drilling
the production from the wells drilled by such designated operator the actual expendi- or operating shall, upon complying with the terms of section 38-08-10, have a lien on
tures required for such purpose, not in excess of what are reasonable, including a the share of production from the spacing un~t accruing to the interest of each of the
reasonable charge for supervision; and the operator shall have the right to receive the other owners for the payment of his proportionate share of such expenses. All the oil
first production from such wells drilled by him thereon which otherwise would be and gas subject to the lien shall be marketed and sold and proceeds applied in pay-
delivered or paid to the other parties jointly interested in the drilling of the well so ment of the expenses secured by such lien as provided for in section 38~08-10.
that the amount due by each of them for his share of the expense of drilling, equip- N.D. CENT. CODE § 38-08-08(2) (Supp. 1985). Section 38-08-10 requires the operator to file for
ping and operating the well may be paid to the operator of the well out of production. record with the register of deeds an affidavit setting forth the amount due and the interest of
ALA. CODE § 9-17-13(e) (19S0). the non-consentor in such production. Foreclosure of the lien is provided in the general require-
.. FLA. STAT. ANN. § 377.28(e)(1) (West Supp. 19S5). ments relating to foreclosures of liens on chattels. [d. § 38-08-10 (1980).
264 JOURNAL OF ENERGY LAW AND POLICY [Vol. 7 1986] POOLING AND UNITIZATION 265

The statute, by essentially allowing free riders, operates in a counter_ share of the produced hydrocarbons. The states disagree, however, on
productive manner. The potential operator will be discouraged from how - and on what costs - the risk factor is to be computed. In five
drilling if he knows that he has to carry the full risk of a dry hole states, including Colorado, the non-consentor is given a free ride as to
:md , in addition, share the benefits from a profitable well with thos~ certain expenses, while other expenses are subject to a one hundred
percent risk penalty.'·
Interest owners who have sat on the sidelines and bore none of the
usual risk of drilling for oil and gas. If the percentage of ownership of Severa! states set the amount of risk penalty as a matter of law in
the ,:"orking int~rests i.s o~er. a minimal amount, then the compulsory the pooling and unitization statute. 37 The responsible administrative
P?olIng mechanism falls. In Its goal~ of ?reventing waste, conserving agency is required to assign the percentage penalty to those expenses
011 and gas, and protectIng correlatIve rIghts. Operators will have to which fall under the various categories listed in the statute. This sys-
attempt to buyout their fellow operators who hold the trump card tem is somewhat counterproductive if the purpose of the penalty is to
because, without their agreement, the putative operator must bear make an assessment for the risk. Not all wells carry with them the
the entire risk of a dry hole. same risk of coming up totally dry or insufficiently productive to pay
Because this type of provision is so counter-productive to the es- off drilling and operating expenses. By having a laundry list approach
sence of the compulsory pooling and unitization idea, most of the ma- in which certain items are recoverable only as to their actua! costs
jor oil producing states have followed the private sector and imposed while others are subject to a penalty, an intent to limit the operator's
a substitute for the risk factor on the nonparticipating working inter- recovery to those items truly at risk in the venture is evident. For
est owner. To this type of statute we now turn. example, surface equipment that is readily moveable is exempt from
the penalty under the Colorado'· and Nebraska'· provisions. This is
B. Risk Penalty Statutes because risk does not exist in the use of that type of equipment;
1. State Approaches to Rish Penalty Provisions. In In re Kohl-
man," the South Dakota Supreme Court concluded that the purpose " COLO. REv. STAT. § 34-60-116(7) (1984); NER. REV. STAT. § 57-909(2) (1984); UTAH CODE
ANN. § 40-8-8(6) (Supp. 1985); WASH. REV. CODE ANN. § 78.52.240 (Supp. 1986); WYo. STAT. §
of imposing a risk penalty on non-consenting working interests own- 30-5-109(g) (1977).
ers is to "relieve the nondrilling interest owner from having to ad- The Colorado statute is typical of this variety. It provides:
vance his proportionate share of the drilling costs, but provide extra (b) Upon the determination of the commission, proper costs recovered by the con-
compensation from production (if oil is found) to the drilling party senting owners of a drilling unit from the nonconsenting owner's share of production
from such a unit shall be as a follows:
who had advanced the entire cost of a 'dry hole.' "•• All risk penalty (1) One hundred percent of the nonconsenting owner's share of the cost of sur-
statutes seek to achieve the objective of compensating the risk-taker face equipment beyond the wellhead connections (including, but not limited to, stock
and preventing the free ride by the non-consenting owner'" As such, tanks, separators, treaters, pumping equipment, and piping) plU$ one hundred per-
t~e pe~alty provisions provide an incentive for voluntary participa- cent of the nonconsenting owner's share of the cost of operation of the well commenc-
ing with first production and contjnuing until the consenting owners have recovered
tIon wIth the proposed operator on terms worked out in the market- such costs. It is the intent that the nonconsenting owner's share of these costs of
place rather than in a governmental context. equipmfmt and operation will be that interest which would have been chargeable to
Within the various states that have risk penalty provisions, a sub- the nonconsenting owner had he initially agreed to pay his share of the costs of the
well from the beginning of the operation.
stantial disparity still exists between approaches. The areas of com- (II) Two hundred percent of that portion of the costs and expenses of staking,
mo~ali~y include the imposition of a specified percentage risk penalty well site preparation, obtaining rights-of-way, rigging up, drilling, reworking, deepen~
whIch IS to be recovered from the non-consentor's proportionate ing or plugging back, testing, and completing the well, after deducting any cash con-
tributions received by the consenting owners, and two hundred percent of that por-
tion of the cost of equipment in the well, including the wellhead connections.
" In re Kohlman, 263 N.W.2d 674 (S.D. 1978). COLO. REV. STAT. § 34-80-116(7) (1984).
84ld. at 675. " See, e.g., COLO. REv. STAT. § 34-60-116(7) (1984); WYo. STAT. § 30-5-109(g) (1977).
" COLO. REV. STAT. § 34-60-116(7) (1984); LA. REv. STAT. ANN. § 30-10 (West Supp. 1985); Ohio saw the difficulties of enforcing a fixed rate risk penalty and amended their statute in
NEB. REV. STAT. § 57-909(2) (1984); N.M. STAT. ANN. § 70-2-17(C) (1978); N.Y. ENVTL. CONSERV. 1967 to adopt a flexible risk penalty provision. For a complete discussion of the Ohio experience
LAW § 23-0901 (McKinney 1984); OHIO REv. CODR ANN. § 1509.27 (Page 1978); fix. NAT. REs. see,6 H. WILLIAMS & C. MEYERS, supra note 17, at 30~31 n.9.
CODE ANN. § 102.052 (Vernon 1978); UTAH CODE ANN. § 40-6-6(6) (Supp. 1985); WASH. REV. \ 38 COLO. REV. STAT. '§ 34-60~1l6(7) (1984); see supra note 36.

CODE ANN. § 78.52.240 (Supp. 1986); WYo. STAT. § 30-5-109(g) (1977). " NEB. REv. STAT. § 57-909(2) (1984).

I
I
266 JOURNAL OF ENERGY LAW AND POLICY [Vol. 7 1986] POOLING AND UNITIZATION 267

rather, depreciation of that equipment is allowed for its intended use. calculating the penalty must be the likelihood or unlikelihood that oil
Thus, a statute taking the Colorado approach attempts to tailor the or gas will be found at the well's proposed location.
penalty provisions to the risk in terms of the equipment being used, Other states provide flexibility by giving the administrative agency
but not as to the geophysical or geologic risk that oil or gas will not the power to set the penalty within a range set out in the statute'"
be found where the drilling takes place. Again, this discretion tends to achieve the penalty's objective of re-
The problem of including a fixed penalty, whether it be limited to warding the risk-taker according to the degree of risk being taken.
specified costs or not, is that it is inconsistent with the purpose of In states that do not delimit the type of activities for which the
imposing a risk penalty because the risks change from well to well. penalty applies, the respective state administrative agencies have va-
There are at least three types of risks that may be involved in drilling rying degrees of discretion to impose the risk penalty and to set its
an oil and gas prospect"· The greatest risk is in drilling a dry hole. A amount. Louisiana specifically provides for a penalty as a "charge for
second risk is encountering unexpected mechanical or geological risk" and requires that the penalty that is to be imposed be fixed at
problems which greatly increase the actual cost of drilling. The third one hundred percent of the actual costs incurred'" The Louisiana
type of risk is the risk of drilling a marginally productive well which Commissioner of Conservation must impose the penalty on persons
will never return to the operator his investment in the drilling and who choose not to participate in the proposed well"·
operating expenses'" Unfortunately, most state statutes and admin- Texas provides greater flexibility in its compulsory pooling order
istrative agencies do not adequately explain the basis for imposing a by allowing the Railroad Commission the. discretion to impose a risk
risk penalty'" charge not to exceed one hundred percent of drilling and completion
Several states which use the laundry list approach attempt to rem- costs." The Railroad Commission, however, must impose a risk
edy the problem of inflexibly mandated risk penalty percentages by charge on all non-consentors"· New Mexico provides the greatest
allowing the responsible state administrative agency to decide flexibility of those states which authorize the use of risk penalties by
whether or not the penalty is to be imposed. Nebraska, while setting giving the Oil Conservation Commission the power to determine not
the penalty for some expenditures at one hundred percent, allows the only the amount of the risk charge, but also whether or not a risk
agency to decide if a penalty is appropriate under the circum-
stances'" However, the statute does not set out the criteria for deter-
" See, e.g., N.M. STAT. ANN. § 70-2-17(C) (197S); N.Y. ENV']'L. CONSERV. LAW § 23-0901 (Mc-
mining when the penalty should be imposed. If the overall purpose of Kinney 1984); UTAH CODE ANN. § 40-6-6(6) (Supp. 1985); WASH. REV. CODE ANN. § 78.52.240
the penalty is to reward the risk taker for bearing someone else's (Supp. 1986).
share of a dry or marginally productive well, the leading factor in " LA. REv. ANN. § 30:1O(2)(b)(i) (West Supp. 1985). Vermont b88 tbe bighest risk penalty
figure: 300 percent is required to be imposed if the lessee chooses not to participate. VT. STAT,
ANN. tit. 29, § 523(c) (Supp. 1985).
4(1 Morris, Compulsory Pooling of Oil and Gas Interests in New Mexico, 3 NAT. RESOURCES J.
" LA. REV. STAT. ANN. § 30:1O(2)(b)(i) (West Supp. 1985). The statute does not differentiate
31S, 326 (1963). between those who voluntarily elect not to participate and those who either want to participate
41 ld. at 325-26.
but cannot bear the financial burden, or those who make a good faith effort to participate but
42 ld. at 326; see also Nutter, Some Engineering Aspects of the New Mexico Compulsory
later become delinquent in their payments due to financially exigent circumstances. Arguably
Pooling Statute, paper delivered to the Mineral Law Section of the State Bar of Texas (July 5, the party who chooses to participate but becomes delinquent should not be subject to a 100
1962), reprinted in 6 H. WILLIAMS & C. MEYERS, OIL AND GAS LAW 29-30 (1985) [hereinafter percent penalty but merely to the typical damages recovery for breach of contract which would
cited as Nutter]. include the amount of the unpaid cost of drilling plus interest on the funds that the operator
43 The Nebraska statute reads in part: had to forward on behalf to the breaching participant.
47 TEX. NAT. RES. CODE ANN. § 102.052(a) (Vernon 1978). See also Windsor Gas Corp. v.
The order shall determine the interest of each owner in the unit, and may provide in
substance that, . . . as to each owner who does not agree, he shall be entitled to Railroad Comm'n, 529 S.W.2d 834 (Tex. Co. App. 1975) wr~t of error dism'd on motion of
receive from the person or persons drilling and operating said well on the unit his parties.
share of the production applicable to his interest, after the person or persons drilling 48 TEX. NAT. RES. CODE ANN. § 102.052(a) (Vernon 1978):

and operating said well have recovered two hundred per cent of that portion of the As to an owner who elects not to pay his proportionate share of the drilling and
costs and expenses of staking, well site preparation, drilling, reworking, deepening or completion costs in advance, the commission shall make provision in the pooling or-
plugging back, testing, completing, and other intangible expenses approved by the
commission chargeable to each owner who does not agree, and one hundred percent [ der for reimbursement solely out of production, to the parties advancing the costs, of
all actual and reasonable drilling, completion, and operating costs plus a charge for
risk not to exceed 100 percent of the- drilling and completion costs.
[of other enumerated costs].
[d.
II
NEB. REV. STAT. § 57-909(2) (19S4).
268 JOURNAL OF ENERGY LAW AND POLICY [Vol. 7 1986] POOLING AND UNITIZATION 269

charge should be imposed!' and costs are not to be imposed if the well does not produce in pay-
The degree of agency discretion may also impact the scope of judi- ing quantities. This provision adds an ambiguity to the right to re-
cial review of risk penalty decisions made by the agency. In Viking cover since it is unclear whether a marginally producing well, which
Petroleum, Inc. v. Oil Conservation Commission," a challenge to a might be sufficient to satisfy a leasehold habendum clause definition
New Mexico pooling order which had imposed a two hundred percent of paying quantities, will be producing in paying quantities so as to
risk penalty was turned back, largely on the traditional notion that allow for the imposition of the penalty." Finally, the operator is only
such determinations were within the particular expertise of the entitled to the penalty if he complies with a series of requirements
agency and should be given great deference by a reviewing court." including filing a petition with the Board and giving to each working
Therefore, agency decisions are going to be difficult to overturn interest owner an offer to participate or farm out his interests to the
where the agencies have been vested with wide discretion by the operator." Therefore, agency decisions are going to be difficult to
pooling and unitization statute. overturn where the agency has been vested with wide discretion by
Mississippi's statute most narrowly confines the discretion of the the pooling and unitization statute.
administrative agency in imposing risk penalties. '2 Mississippi is also 2. Criteria By Which Agencies Determine The Risk Penalty. In
unique because it is the only state which gives the operator, not the states where agencies have discretion to determine the risk penalty,
non-consentor, an option to carry the non-consentor's interest or there is a paucity of legislative guidance regarding criteria to be con-
seek, in addition to the pro rata share of expenses, a penalty of up to sidered by the agency in determining whether a risk penalty should
250 percent of such costs. '3 The statute also requires that the penalty be imposed, and what the amount should be if a penalty is warranted
by the facts. There is little judicial precedent discussing the underly-
411 N.M. STAT. ANN. § 70·2-17(C) (1978). Ohio has a similar provision but may allow the opera-
ing Commission decisions in which discretion is given by the statute.
tor to continue to recoup a 200 percent penalty from the continuing operating expenses for the All that the New Mexico Supreme Court stated in the Viking Petro-
life of the productive well. This result would truly be too harsh and overcompensate the opera- leum decision was that the decision on the amount of risk penalty
tor for the risks he had taken. OHIO REv. CODE ANN. § 1509.27 (Page 1978); see also Williams & imposed was, by its very nature, an ad hoc factually determined issue
Meyers, Petroleum Conservation in Ohio, 26 OHIO ST. L.J. 581, 608 (1965).
lJ,O Viking Petroleum, Inc. v. Oil Conservation Comm'n., 100 N.M. 451, 672 P.2d 280 (1983).
which was to be given broad deference by a reviewing court."
111 Viking Petroleum is a fascinating Clllie. HEyeO wanted to drill a well to test several dif- Certain factual issues are obviously relevant to an agency making a
ferent formations. Viking wanted to participate in the expenses only through the shallower risk penalty provision given the penalty's purpose of compensating
formations. The Commission denied the Viking petition for partial participation and gave them
a limited time to participate or be carried with the imposition of a 200 percent risk penalty.
the risk taker and avoiding free rides. The major factual issue relates
Viking chose not to participate, and brought an action seeking to overturn the Commission's to a determination or quantification of the amount of risk carried by
order denying them the right to partial participation. 672 P.2d at 281. The Supreme Court the operator. Factors include the proposed well's proximity to other
decision treated the matter of partial participation and risk penalty as a matter of law, rather
than as an issue of fact. It nonetheless applied a substantial evidence standard, which is nor-
mally reserved to judicial review of agency findings of fact. Id, at 283. The court reviewed the faith effort to (i) negotiate with each nonconsenting owner to have said owner's inter-
evidence presented to the Commission in a deferential way, making all reasonable inferences in est voluntarily integrated into the unit, (ii) notify each nonconsenting owner of the
favor of the Commission and excluding from consideration all evidence· unfavorable to the names of all owners with drilling rights whO have agreed to integrate any interests in
Commission's findings. Id. the unit, (iii) ascertain the address of each nonconsenting owner, (iv) give each non-
The court concluded: consenting owner written notice of the 'proposed operation, specifying the work to be
The grantipg or refusal to grant forced pooling of multiple zones with an election to partici· performed, the location, proposed depth, objective formation and the estimated cost
pate in less than all zones, the amount of costs to be reimbursed to the operator, and the of the proposed operation, and (v) to offer each nonconsenting owner the opportunity
percentage risk charge to be assessed, if any, are determinations to be made by the Commis- to lease or farm out on reasonable·· terms, or to participate in the cost and risk of
sion on a case-to·case basis and upon the particular facts in each case. developing and operating the unit well involved, on reasonable terms, by agreeing in
Id. at 284; see also Rutter & Wilbanks Corp. v. Oil Conservation Comm'n, 87 N.M. 286, 289- writing, then the operator may petition the board to allow it to charge alternate
291,532 P.2d 582, 585-87 (1975) (findings of Commission are sufficient; orders are supported by charges as hereinafter set out (alternate to and in lieu of the charges provided for in
substantial evidence). subsection (l)(b) above).
~1I MISS. CODE ANN. § 53·3-7 (Supp. 1985); see also McDavid, Mississippi's New Operator MISS. CODE ANN. § 53-3-7(2)(.) (Supp. 1985).
Risk Compensation Statute, THE LANDMAN, Nov. 1984, at 7. .. Id. § 53-3·7.
II~ Section 53-3-7(2)(a) of the Mississippi Code provides: MId
In the event that a majority of the drilling interests. in a. drilling unit has voluntarily 66 Viking Petroleum, Inc. v. Oil Cons~rvation, Comm'n, 100 N.M. 451, 672 P.2d 280 (1983);
consented to the drilling of a unit well thereon, and the operator has made a good see supra note 51.
I
t
270 JOURNAL OF ENERGY LAW AND POLICY [Vol. 7 1986] POOLING AND UNITIZATION 271
successful wells, the geologic information regarding the known the compulsory pooling process was not triggered. B'
reserves in the area, and the productivity of any existing offset wells The amount of the penalty itself is not determinative of whether it
in the area. 07 These factors all relate to the issue of whether - and . is fair or reasonable. Undoubtedly the negotiation process that would
if so, how much - oil or gas will be found. Other factors may relat~ take place in a voluntary pooling agreement would better reflect the
to the speed at which the operator can be expected to recoup his amount of risk that knowledgeable parties predict is encompassed by
investment assuming the geologic information was correct. Speed cri- the proposed drilling plan. The compulsory pooling process is re-
teria include current and expected demand of the product, location quired to bring parties together who cannot agree on a risk penalty or
of the nearest pipelines for gas transportation, if gas is the expected other provisions. The need fot a compulsory process stems from a
mineral to be discovered, depth of expected find and the cost of need to achieve important public objectives of protecting correlative
drilling.'· rights, preventing waste, and encouraging efficient development of
Texas has a unique requirement which must be met before an op- the oil and gas resource. In In re Kohlman, B4 the court reviewed a
erator can seek to force pool other working interest owners. The Commission's determination that a one hundred percent penalty was
Texas Railroad Commission cannot exercise jurisdiction until the reasonable, even though the operator had sought a two hundred fifty
proposed operator has made a fair and reasonable offer to voluntarily percent penalty and the non-consenter had apparently agreed in pri-
pool the other working interests.'· In Windsor Gas Corp. u. Railroad vate negotiations to a one hundred fifty percent penalty. B' Because a
Commission, B. the court had to ascertain whether a voluntary offer to successful well was located about three-quarters of a mile from the
pool was fair and reasonable. The offer required a one hundred per- proposed well site, a smaller risk penalty should have been imposed
cent penalty be attached to the other working interest owner should because the risk of a dry hole was less. The court concluded that the
he opt not to participate. B1 The operator was planning to drill eight Commission's one hundred percent penalty was reasonable even
wells within the area to be pooled because there had been production though it was a smaller penalty than the non-consentor had volunta-
on both sides of the proposed drilling locations, and the region had a . rily agreed to.·B
long history of productive drilling. In addition there had been an 84.6 The Commission's decision is probably supportable under an arbi-
percent success rate in drilling during the previous year, excluding trary and capricious or substantial evidence scope of judicial review
offset wells. B2 The court held that there was essentially no risk in the given the closeness of the productive well. The result, however, is
drilling activities. Therefore, an offer to have a one hundred percent probably inefficient from an economic viewpoint because it gives to
penalty in excess of actual costs was not "fair and reasonable," and the non-consentor more than he had agreed to in the market place.
In states like Texas where a voluntary offer to pool must be made,
the Commission should give great weight to both the operator's offer
G'1 Nutter, supra note 42.
on the risk penalty and the carried interest owner's counter-offer, if
6'8 Holmes v. Corporation Comm'n, 466 P.2d 630 (Okla. 1970). The court in Holmes dealt

with a ~on-consenting mineral owner who had burdened his working interest with a very high any was made. Where the agency has credible evidence placing lower
production payment. Under those circumstances the working interest owner in Oklahoma and upper limits on the amount of the penalty, the agency should
would have been faced with an election between participation or transfer of his interest with restrict its exercise of discretion to those limits because they are the
the payment of a bonus. However, because of the high production payments burdening the
interest, it would have been likely that the lessee would have received nothing for his interest. best evidence of the market place valuation of the resource.·7
See infra note 88. Therefore the operator asked for a third option, namely being carried with a
risk penalty. The court upheld a risk penalty of 250% primarily because the well was a deep
well with concomitantly higher costs and longer period of payout if the gas was found. Id. at 63 [d. at 836-37; see TEX. NAT. RES. CODE ANN. § 102.013(b) (Vernon 1984); the definition of a

633. fair and reasonable offer was discussed in Carson v. Railroad Comm'n of Texas, 669 S.W.2d
Ge TEX. NAT. R~s. CODE ANN. § 102.013(b) (Vernon 1984). See generally Smith, The Texas
315, 318 (Tex. 19S4).
Compulsory Poolmg Act (pt. 2), 44 TEx. L. REV. 387, 393 (1966) (describing possible application .. In re Kohlman, 263 N.W.2d 674 (S.D. 1975).
of the Commission's requirement). 6G [d. at 679. A previous agreement between the parties on another tract of land had led to a

60 Windsor Gas Corp. v. Railroad Comm'n., 529 S.W.2d 834 (Tex. Civ. App. 1975) writ of
voluntary agreement in which a 250 percent penalty was mutually acceptable. [d. at 678.
1I6 [d. at 679. -
error dism'd on motion of parties.
67 [d. at 678·79. The court said that the penalty is based on several unidentified factors,
61 Id. at 835.

62 Id. at 837.
including proximity to successful wells.- Nonetheless, the parties who have the greatest to gain
or lose are the best judges of what the risk is. Where the non-consentor has voluntarily agreed
POOLING AND UNITIZATION 273
272 JOURNAL OF ENERGY LAW AND POLICY [Vo!. 7 1986]
C. Option States a permanent or temporary basis. The permanent transfer, which is
merely a total assignment of the working interest in exchange for a
Several p.ooling. and uni~ization statutes specify that the non-con_ cash consideration, eliminates the owner from further development of
~entor be gwen either deSignated or undesignated options before his the field. The second option turns into a risk penalty option because
mterest can be force pooled. Several states including Illinois 6S P the assignment of the working interest is for a limited time, subject
. 69 V' . . 70 d W " , enn~
syIvama, ~r~mla, an est Virginia,71 specifically include a risk to recoupment. 76 While not labeled a risk penalty, the additional sum
pen.alty prOVISIOn as one of the qesignated options that must be made mentioned must be related to the carried status and the lack of risk.
available
d t th to hthe non-consenting working interest owners. Ill'mOls . man- By legislative default the state agency is given wide latitude in set-
.a es at t e non-~o~sentor be given alternatives, including: 1) the ting the criteria used to determine if a penalty is to be imposed and
right ~o surrender hiS mteres~ to participating owners for a reasona- the range of possible penalties in issuing the compulsory pooling
ble pnc.e .to be set by the parties or by the Mining Board, 2) the ri ht
to. participate on a noncarried basis, and 3) the right to be carrred order.
Several states, including South Dakota,77 merely provide that the
with a penalty of fifty percent of the drilling, testing and completio order must include just and reasonable alternatives, without men-
costs. of the well."' Where the compulsory order does not include ~ tioning what those alternatives are." In In re Kohlman,7. the South
elec~lOn, the order is void, but only as to that part which relates to Dakota Supreme Court upheld the ability of the state agency to pro-
the Impos.ed penalty.73 That part of the order pooling the interest vide a risk penalty as one of the alternatives to be presented to the
and allowmg the operator to drill will be deemed valid. 74 s non-consenting working interest owner. so While the right to impose a
A~kansas a.uth?rizes a somewhat different option for its non-con- penalty was not specifically mentioned in the statute, the court
sentmg ~ork.mg mterest owner."" Besides the option to participate, treated the power to impose the penalty as necessarily implied from
the workmg mterest owner can transfer his rights to the operator on the general power to provide just and reasonable alternatives for non-
consenting mineral and working interest owners. The Board, in carry-
to a 150 percent penalty there seems to be no reason to go below it since the person t
th m by the decision has already
affected . determined what the risk was. ConstlamIng. . th e agencymosto
e 0 era and counter-offers might encourage inflating and deflating the figures and discourage 76 The provision states in part:
[d.
vol~~ agreements. In some circumstances the agency should be able to set risk penalt Such order shall also provide that an owner who does not affirmatively elect to par-
pro~lSlons re.gardless of the figures met by the parties, jf for example, new geological evidence i~ ticipate in the risk and cost of such operations shall transfer his rights in such drilling
aV.81lable or if ODe or both of the parties offers are deemed to be unreasonable or made in bad unit and the production from the uIiit well to the parties who elect to participate
faIth. therein for a reasonable consideration and on a reasonable basis. which in the absence
.. ILL. ANN. STAT. ch. 96'h, § 5436(d) (Smith-Hurd 1979). of agreement between the parties, shall be determined by the Commission. Such
transfer may be either a permanent transfer or may be for a limited period pending
e9 PA. STAT. ANN. tit. 58, § 408(c) (Purdon 1964)'(provides for a 100 percent penalty)
recoupment out of the share of production attributable to the interest of such non-
" VA. CODE § 45.1-302(C) (Supp. 1985). .
participating owner by the participating parties of an amount equal to the share of
:: w. VA. CODE § 22-8·7(b)(6) (1985) (provides for a 100 percent penalty).
the costs that would have been borne by such- non-participating party had he partici-
ILL. ANN. STAT. eh. 96Y" § 5436(d) (Smith-Hurd 1979).
pated in such operations. plus an addtional sum to be fixed by the Commission.
" Newkirk v. Bigard, 125m. App. 3d 454, 462, 466 N.E.2d 243, 248 (19S4). Although this
77 S. D. CODIFIED LAWS AN~. § 45-9-31 (1983).
case l~volved an un~eased nuneral owner, the issue is the same for working interest owners. In
" IDAHO CODE § 47.322 (1977); Ky. REV. STAT. § 353.640 (1983); S.C. CODE ANN. § 48-43-
~e.wk;r~. t.he,CQUlt l~terpreted the compulsory pooling statute as requiring the Mining Board
me u e In Its poolIng order reasonable alternatives for the non-consenting mineral owners to 340(C) (Supp. 1984).
choose from, even though the statute used the phrase "if requested" to modify th . t " In re Kohlman, 263 N.W.2d 674 (S.D. 1978).
of "d' It . , ' " ' e reqUlremen
proVl mg a e~natlves. 4~6 N.E.2d at 248 (quoting ILL. REv. STAT. ch. 96'12, § 5436 (Smith- 80 [d. at 675. The order provided in part:

Hurd 1979», WhIle the notice for the hearing included a provision relating to alternatives the That the operator (Depco) is hereby authorized to withhold the following costs and
ac~~al order required Newkirk. an unleased owner, to participate. Id. at 247. ' charges from production:·The pro rata share of reasonable well costs attributable to
each nonconsenting working interest owner who had not paid his share of estimated
t thId. at. 248.thWhere..the non-consentor chooses not to partier'pate m' the h earIng
. or respon d
o e notices. e MmIng Board can avoid a problem by having its order state that if the non- well costs within 30 days from the date the schedule of estimated well costs is fur-
consentor does not respond to the notice within a specified time. the pre-designated option will nished to him. As a charge for ~he risk involved in the drilling of the well, 100 percent
be de~med to have heen selected. This procedure will prevent the nonconsenter from unduly of the pro rata share of reasonable well costs attributable to each nonconsenting
delaymg the ?perators' schedule merely by sitting on the election which the statute mandates working interest owner who has not paid his share of estimated well costs within 30

I
h e must be gIven. days from the date the schedule -of estimated well costs is furnished to him .. , .
" ARE. STAT. ANN. § 53-1l5(A-I)(e) (1971). Id.
[Vol. 7 POOLING AND UNITIZATION 275
274 JOURNAL OF ENERGY LAW AND POLICY 1986]

ing out the generally stated purpose of preventing waste in the devel- fair and reasonable bonus to be determined by the governmental
opment of the state's oil and gas resources, was within its power :gency.a. Soon after the adoption of the statewide com~~sory pool-
when it chose the risk penalty alternative.al ing law, the Corporation Commission issued an order glvmg ~ non-
States that authorize the use of alternatives provide a more realis- consentor those same options. The order was attacked as bemg an
tic replica of the actual marketplace for working interests and, there- unconstitutional taking of property without just compensation and. as
fore, more closely achieve what the market cannot do because of the not being authorized by the statute. In Anderson v. Corporatwn
ruIe of capture. As stated earlier, operators who seek to jointly oper- Commission,aa the Oklahoma Supreme Court upheld the validity of
ate a pool or reservoir have several choices available to them in order the compulsory pooling statute and the Commission order which es-
to persuade the other owners to join in their venture. By giving the sentially required the non-consentor to partici~ate.or a~nvolunt~:ilY
administrative agency the same kind of alternatives, the agency can sell his working interests to the operator for a faIr prt~e. In ad~lt~on
tailor an order which reflects what the market would bear were it not to the straight cash bonus alternative, the CorporatIOn CommISSIOn
for the impediments placed in the road to voluntary agreements. has issued orders combining a cash bonus with an overriding royalty
interest. It also ordered the transfer of an overriding royalty in lieu of
D. Silent States a cash bonus. aa In determining the amount of cash bonus and/or
The final group of states essentially does not make any specific overriding royalty to be paid the non-consentor, the Corporation
mention in their pooling and unitization statutes of what to do with Commission examines available geologic information regarding the
the non-participating owner's interest. Most of these states' statutes likelihood of success, plus any analogous sales of working interest in
contain only the general instruction to the Board that the order must the area and the results of drilling in the immediate region"·
be on "terms and conditions that are just and reasonable, and will The addition of the overriding royalty to the buyout alternatives
afford to the owner of each tract . . . the opportunity to recover or shifts some of the risk of a dry hole to the non-consentor. But since
receive his just and equitable share of the oil or gas."a2 the non-consentor's interest is cost-free, he benefits from a margin-
Of all these states, Oklahoma by far has the most highly developed ally productive well which never pays out because he receives his roy-
administrative and judicial doctrine to fill in the lacunae caused by a alty regardless of the well's profitability. Because the transfer of
compulsory pooling statute which does not deal with the problem of
non-consenting working interest 'owners. a8 The alternatives that have .. OKLA. STAT. ANN. tit. 52, § 87.1(e) (1984 & Supp. 1985).
developed in the Oklahoma Corporation Commission to deal with the 86 Anderson v. Corporation Comm'n., 327 P.2d 699 (Okla. 1958); see also Superior Oil ?o. v.

non-consentor have as their antecedents the municipaI ordinances Oklahoma Corp. Comm'n, 242 P.2d 454, 458 (Okla. 1952) (Commission ord~r requiring ~meral
interest owner to pay $85,000 wit1)in 10 qays or accept $500 per acre for Its lease modifi~d).
that were the predecessors to statewide compulsory pooling stat- 87 Anderson 327 P .2d at 702·03. This notion of a forced sale has been analogized to a pXlvate
utes.a4 The two alternatives normally given to municipal lot owners eminent domain proceeding. If a party chooses not to or is unable to participat~ in the we.ll
who could only drill a single well in one city block were: electing to costs through the payment of cash or a bond, the Commissi.on:s actions ~equi~e him ~ sell hiS
share proportionately in the costs; or not participating and accepting property interest to the operator at a price which the CommissIon determmes IS t~e fair mark~t
value. One could analogize this situation to the common statutory grant of emment d~malD
powers to public utilities operating under a government permit or certificate of conven~e?~.
SlId. at 677-78. See, e.g., TEx. REV. ClY. STAT. ANN. art. 1436 '(Vernon 1980) (giving to certain public utilitIes
.. MICa. STAT, ANN, § 13,139(13) (Callaghan 1981); see alsa GA, CODE ANN, § 43-706(.)(1) right to condemn land for right 'of way purposes).
88 For a more complete discussion of the alternatives available under the Oklahoma statute,
(Supp. 1985) (no standards outlined); OR. REV. STAT. § 520.220 (1983) Gust and reasonable con-
ditions); TENN, CODE ANN, § 60-1-202 (Supp. 19&5) (uo standards outliued). see Nesbitt, A Primer on Forced Pooling of Oil and. Gas Interests in Oklahoma, 50 OKLA. RA.J.
83 The Oklahoma statute provides in part: 648 (1979).
6& In Home-Stake Royalty Corp. v. CorporationComm'n, 594 P.2d 1207 (O~. 1979~, the
Where, however, such owners have not agreed to pool their interests and where one
such separate owner has drilled or proposes to drill a well . . . the Commission . . . court said that confidential geologic information need not be provided by the poolmg applicant,
shall. . . require such owners to pool and develop their lands in the spacing unit as a but that evidence of the fair market value of the non-consenting working interest owners may
unit. . . . All orders requiring such pooling shall be made. . . upon such terms and be determined by looking at the teJIDs and prices given by other lessees or in recent leases in
conditions as are just and reasonable . . . . the area. ld. at 1209·10. But in Miller v. Corporation Comm'n, 635 P.2d 1006 (Okla. 1~81), the
OKLA, STAT. ANN, tit. 52, § 87.1(e) (19S4 & Supp. 1985). court rejected an attack on an order setting a bonus of $75/acre and a 118th override even
84 Id.; see also Curlee, The Problem of the "Free-Riding" Lessee and Some Suggested Solu-
though the state had, in a sealed bid auction, received a larger bonus and royalty on a nearby
tions, 9 INST. ON MIN. L. 21, 24 (1962). tract located in the same unit. Id. at 1007-09.
f
t
POOLING AND UNITIZATION 277
276 JOURNAL OF ENERGY LAW AND POLICY [Vol. 7 1986]
be afforded an opportunity to recover their just and equi~able share
working interests in the oil and gas industry usually involves some il and gas. 9 ' An owner is defined by statute to mclude all
form of overriding royalty interest as the prime consideration, inclu- of the o . . 9' An unIeased
rsons possessing the right to dnll for 011 and gas.
sion of that option by the Commission reflects the realities of the ~ineral owner clearly has the right to drill or the power to lease to
operation of the free market system and should be encouraged.
The Oklahoma Corporation Commission has allowed a fourth alter-
native under its just and reasonable order powers-the inclusion of a the persons owning those interests may popl their interests for. the ~ev.elopment ~nd
operation of the spacing unit. In the absence of voluntary poolIng wIthm the spacmg
risk penalty. Although the risk penalty option has been upheld on a unit, the board, upon the application of an interested person, may ent:r an order
number of occasions,·· it does not appear to be a preferred option; pooling all interests in the spacing unit for the development and operatIOn th~~eof.
and the courts have unanimously upheld the Commission's decision The pooling order shall be made after hearing and shall be upon terms and ~ondltlo~S
not to include the option when it issues an order.· ' In the view of one that are just and reasonable and that afford to the ?wne: of each tract or mterest In
the spacing unit the opportunity to recover or receIve WIthout unnecessary expen~es
author/practitioner, the Commission feels that the other options bet- his just and equitable share of the oil or gas produced and sav.ed from the .spacIn.g
ter allocate the risk of a dry hole and the rewards of a producing well unit. Operations incident to the drilling of a well upon any portIOn of a spacmg umt
than the penalty provisions.·2 covered by a pooling order shall be considered, for all purposes, the conduct of the
operations upon each separately owned tract in the spacing unit b;y the sev~ral own-
III. THE NON-CONSENTING UNLEASED MINERAL OWNER erS thereof. That portion of the production allocated to each tract I?cluded In a spac~
. g unit covered by a pooling order shall when produced be consIdered for all pur-
A. The Silent Treatment :oses to have been produced from the tract by a well drilled th~reon.
(2) (a) The pooling order shall provide for the drilling an~ operatIng of. a well on the
While almost all of the state statutes provide some formal guidance spacing unit and for the payment of the cost thereof, whIch cost may Include a rea-
sonable charge for supervision, handling, and storage. As to each owner who refu~es
and standards for the state agency regarding the terms which may be to pay his share of the costs of drilling and operating the well, the o~der shall proVlde
imposed on the nonconsenting working interest owner that oversees for payment of his share of the cost out of and only. out of production fr?m the well
the compulsory pooling or unitization process, it is somewhat surpris- allocable to his interest in the spacing unit, excludmg royalty or other mterest not
ing that most state statutes make no mention whatsoever of what the obligated to pay any part of the cost thereof, and excluding the royalty provided for
in subsection (2)(c) of this section. If a dispute arises as to the cost, the board by
agency is to do when unleased lands are contained within a pooled or order shall determine the proper cost. The order may provid~ in substance that the
unitized area.· 3 The fact that the statute is silent does not necessarily owners who agree to share in the cost of drilling and operatIn~ ~e well. are; unless
mean that unleased owners fall in the lacunae and present impedi- they agree otherwise, entitled to receive, subject to royalty or SImIlar oblIgatIOns, all
of the production of the well until they' have recovered all of the c~sts out of ~he
ments to the compulsory pooling process. Montana's compulsory production, and thereafter all of the owners in the spacing. u~it are entItled to receIve
pooling statute provides a good illustration of how unleased owners (
;
their respective shares of the production of the well as theIr mterest may appear after
would be treated even though they are neglected by specific statutory deducting their respective s;hares of current operating costs. . '
language.·' Under the Montana statutory scheme, all "owners" must Professor Smith in his analysis of the then-nascent Mineral Interest Pooling Act I~ Texas
also discussed the problem of the unleased owner. Sniith, The Texas Compulsory Poolmg Act,
44 TEX, L. REv. 387, 405-06 (1966). He suggested that it would be proper, although not
110 See, e.g., Holmes v. Corporation Comm'n, 466 P.2d 630, 633 (Okla. 1969). mandatory, for the Commission to force pool unleased o~ers u~~er term.s where they 7 ere
III See Texas Oil & Gas Corp. v. Rein, 534 P.2d 1280, 1282 (Okla. 1974); Ranola Oil Co. v. given an option to participate as to %th of the interest and In addItion receive a cost-free !hth
Corporation Comm'n, 460 P.2d 415, 417 (Okla. 1969); Wakefield v. State, 306 P.2d 305, 308 royalty. [d. at 406. A problem that Professor Smith foresaw was the ~ovement away from t::
(Okla. 1957). standard l/sth royalty. If nearby lessors hai::lleased for more than a Vsth royalty, should t
IIlI. Nesbitt, supra note 88, at 652-53. This might lead to a conclusion that the Commission
unleased owner be forced to accept' a J/s th royalty? Professor Smith thought not m:-d contra~ted
favors owners who are not in the oil arid gas industry and who cannot bear the financial risk of the Texas provision with other states in which the statute mandated the receIpt of a .!hth
the all or nothing shot at a producing well. But the cases do not necessarily agree with that royalty by an unleased owner. Id. at' 406. See N~M. STAT. ANN. § 70-2-17(c) (1978). See mira
conclusion, and it has not been stated to be a factor in the Commission's decision to allow an text accompanying notes 137 to 141.
owner to be carried with a penalty. " MONT. CODE ANN. § 82-11-202(1) (1985).
98 Approximately 24 states which have a compulsory pooling or unitization statute or both do The statute provides in part:
99

not deal with the problem of the unleased owner. See, e.g., COLO. REV. STAT. § 24~60-116(7) "Owner" ineans the person who has the right to drill into and produce from a pool
(1984); ILL. ANN. STAT. ch. 96V" § 5436(d) (Smith-Hurd 1979); OHIO REv. CODE ANR § 1509.27 and to appropriate the oil or gas he produces there from either .for himself or ~thers
(Page 1978); TEX. NAT. RES. CODE § 102.052 (Vernon 1978). or for himself and others, and the ~rm includes all persons holdmg such authorIty by
k MONT. CODE ANN. § 82-11-202(1) (1985) provides: or through him.
When two or more separately owned tracts are embraced within a spacing unit or MONT. CODE ANN. § 82-11-101(8) (1985).
when there are separately owned interests in all or a part of the spacing unit, then
278 JOURNAL OF ENERGY LAW AND POLICY POOLING AND UNITIZATION
[Vol. 7 1986] 279
another the right to drill. 97 Therefore, the compulsory pooling order maining fraction, % ths, becomes the equivalent of a working interest,
cannot ignore the unleased owner and must resolve any problems and the unleased owner is then treated as any other working interest
caused by his inclusion within the pooled or unitized area.·· In addi- owner whose leasehold interest is being pooled.'·· The statutory pro-
tion, the Montana provision dealing with the right to participate in vision essentially creates a leasehold interest and arbitrarily allocates
the well costs also uses the term "owner," which would include the a 'Ia th royalty to the unleased owner as if he had leased the land to
unleased mineral owner.·· Therefore, the unleased owner would have himself while retaining a '/a th royalty. That result may not have been
to at least be given the opportunity to participate in the well as a unfair at a time when the 'Ia th royalty was almost universally used;
working interest owner.'OO but, today there is really no standardized royalty in the oil and gas
The problem with ignoring the unleased owner is that, as an field, and if anything, the 'Ia th royalty is below the market standard
"owner," he is in many circumstances treated solely as a working in- in today's leasing activities.
~erest o,",:ner, alth?ugh he has in essence both a working and royalty One response to the artificial setting of the royalty at '/a th is to
mterest m the mmeral estate.'O' An essential attribute of the un- allow the unleased owner's royalty interest to be directly tied to the
leased mineral estate is the right to receive royalty upon its leasing to prevailing royalty rates in the leases which have been signed in the
and production by another.'o, Merely treating him as a working in- pooled or unitized area. Again, that will best reflect the true value of
terest owner would give him the right to participate in the costs of the unleased owner's interest and most closely compensate him for
the well but deny him his right to receive a cost free royalty regard- the value of his mineral interest, North Dakota has sought to achieve
less of whether the well ever makes a profit. that result by enacting a compulsory. pooling statute which gives to
B. The %-Yil Solution the unleased owner the "weighted average royalty interest of the
leased tracts within the spacing unit" but never less than a 'Is th
The approach taken by the majority of state pooling and unitiza- interest.,oB
tion statutes which specifically treat the unleased owner is simply to The North Dakota provision was challenged by an operator of a
convert the unleased owner's mineral interest into two distinct inter- pooled unit who argued that the Commission was without authority
ests, a 'Is th cost-free royalty and a % ths working interest, and then to establish a lessor-lessee relationship where none existed and that
plug those interests into the prevailing statutory provisions. '03 consequently, the unleased owner's full interest was essentially that
Within this group there are two different approaches as to the of a working interest owner who could join in and pay the propor-
amount of royalty due the unleased owner. In Arkansas, for example, tionate share of drilling costs or be carried subject to a lien against
the statute specifically limits an unleased owner to a 'Is th royalty af- his pro rata share of production.'·7 In a state such as North Dakota
ter there has been a pooling or unitization of his interest.'·' The re- where the working interest owner gets a free ride without a risk pen-
alty, the benefits to an unleased owner are substantial.,oB Not only
fl1R. HEMINGWAY, THE LAW OF OIL AND GAS 33-34 (2d ed. 1983). does he receive a cost-free royalty out of the first barrel of produc-
98 For other statutory schemes similar to that of Montana see ARIZ. REV. STAT. ANN. §§ 27-
501(14) through 505(A) (1976); IDAHO CODE §§ 47-31SUJ through 322 (1977); TEx. NAT. REs.
CODE § 102.012 & .052 (Vernon 1975).
105 Once the Vath interest is classified as a working interest, the various state approaches take
" MONT. CODE ANN. § 82-11-202(2) (19S5).
100Id. over and the unleased owner will be treated as if he had leased the land to himself. See supra
section II. .
101 Slawson v. North Dakota Industrial Comm'n., 339 N.W.2d 772 (N.D. 1983). 108 The North Dakota provision provides in part:
102 HEMINGWAY, supra note 97, at 34-36.
For the purposes of this section and section 38-08-10, any unleased mineral interest
'" See, e.g., ARK. STAT. ANN. § 53-115(A-l)(e) (1971); NEB. REv. STAT. § 57-909(2) (1984); pooled by virtue of this section shall be entitled to a cost-free royalty interest equal
~.M. STAT. ANN. 70-2-17(C) (197S); N.D. CENT. CODE § 3S-0S-0S (Supp. 19S5); OKLA. STAT. ANN. to the acreage weighted -average royalty interest of the leased tracts within the spac-
tIt. 52, § S7.1(e) (19S4 & Supp. 19S5).
ing unit, but in no event shall the royalty- interest of an unleased tract be less than a
104 ARK. STAT. ANN. § 53-115(A-l)(e) (1971). The statute provides:
one-eighth interest. The remainder of the unlesed interest shall be treated as a lessee
In .the event there is an unleased mineral interest or interests in any such ,drilling or cost bearing interest.
umt, the owner thereof shall be regarded as the owner of a royalty interest· to the
extent of a one-eighth (Va th) interest in and to said unleased mineral interest and r N.D. CENT. CODE § 3S-0S-0S(I) (Supp. 19S5).
107 Slawson, 339 N.W.2d at 775-76.

[t
such royalty interest shall not be affected by the provisions of subparagraphs (c) and 108 See supra text accompanying notes 22~3l for a complete discussion of the free ride alter-
(d) ahove.
native for non-consenting working interest owners.
280 JOURNAL OF ENERGY LAW AND POLICY [Vol. 7 1986] POOLING AND UNITIZATION 281
tion, but he also gets his free ride so that, if the well ever becomes
profitable, he suddenly becomes a silent partner to the risk-taking son v. Corporation Commission.''' In Anderson, unlike Slawson, the
operator, sharing proportionately in the good fortunes of an abun- operator was happy with the order giving the unleased owner his pro-
portionate share of a Vs th royalty and subjecting hi8 'Va th working
dantly producing well. It is therefore not surprising that an operator
interest to the option of paying a proportionate share of the well
would challenge the statutory scheme as giving the unleased owner
more than the market would bear. costs or accepting a cash bonus in exchange for the transrer of the
working interest. ll5 The court had no difficulty accepting the validity
In Slawson v. North Dakota Industrial Commission,"o the court of the order, both as to the inclusion of the I/S th royalty "6 and the
was able to rebut the operator's charge that the statute created a options afforded the unleased owner regarding the 'Va th working in-
lease where none was consented to, by concluding that an unleased terest that the statute carved out of the unleased mineral estate!l7
mineral interest has within it several constituent parts, including the Another way of achieving the 'Va -Va solution is through the defini-
royalty and working interests. n • Since the statutory command is to tion section of the pooling and unitization statute. That i8 the ap-
provide a "just and reasonable" order, the legislative determination proach taken by West Virginia, which defines an operator in terms
that the unleased owner is entitled to full compensation for his con- that would include an unleased mineral owner, but only to the extent
stituent rights is reasonable!n The court ignored the fact that an of a 'Va ths interest. 116 The unleased mineral owner is also considered
unleased owner's right to royalty is normally accompanied by a trans- a royalty owner as to a Vs th interest. That is important because the
fer of the working interest to a lessee. The unleased owner changes a statute prevents the drilling on the tract of an unleased royalty
risk-bearing interest to a risk and cost-free interest. On the other owner without his prior written consent!'· The unleased owner is
hand, if an unleased owner drills his own well, he does not receive given one of the two option8 afforded working interest owners as to
any risk and cost-free royalty but merely receives the profits, if any, the .'Vs ths working interest he has pur8uant to the 8tatute. 12 '
from his business venture. ll2 North Dakota and other states which
treat the unleased owner in this way provide, in effect, a windfall for C. The!-1J th Solution
the mineral owner where the non-consenting working interest owner While the unlea8ed owner may be getting a windfall in the states
is given a free ride on the back of the operator!13 providing him with both a cost free working and royalty interest
The inclusion of unleased mineral owners in compulsory pooling share in the pooled production, the California approach seemingly
orders has been accepted in Oklahoma since the early case of Ander- penalizes the unleased owner by reducing his unleased mineral estate
to a mere royalty interest. 12 ' While the statute has only limited appli-
'"' Slawson. 339 N.W.2d 772 (N.D. 1983).
llO Id. at 775-76.
114 Anderson v. Corporation Comm'n., 327 P.2d 699 (Okla. 1958).
111Id. at 777. The court also disagreed with the operator's contention that the statutory IH; [d. at 700-01. The unleased owner also cannot complain about the location of the well on
provision providing for a lien against the oil and gas produced applied both to the royalty and his land nor the use of his land for access to and from a well located elsewhere on the pooled or
working interests of the unleased owner. The court noted that the pooling and spacing unit spacing unit. See, e.g., McDaniel v. Moyer, 662 P.2d 309 (Okla; I9B3); Cormack v. Wil-Mc
provisions essentially gave the operator the monopoly on drilling a well. The unleased owner Corp., 661 P.2d 525 (Okla. 1983); Texas Oil and Gas Corp. v. Rein, 534 P.2d 1277 (Okla. 1974).
would therefore be deprived of leasing his land since no further wells could be drilled on the 116 Anderson, 327 P.2d at 70l.

property. Thus, it would not be improper to provide both a cost-free royalty and a free ride 117 [d. at 702~03. The Oklahoma statute provides in part:
working interest, subject to the statutory lien, to the unleased non~consenting owner. Id. at 778- For the purpose of this section, the owner or owners of oil and gas rights in and under
79.
an unleased tract of land shall be regarded as a lessee to the extent of a seven-eighths
m Of course it might be possible for the unleased owner to lease the minerals to himself
providing for a royalty interest in excess of the royalties secured in the other leases pooled in
the area. The statute may in effect encourage such transactions, although they may be viewed
as a totally sham transaction. It is not unheard of for an unleased mineral owner, especially a
cotenant, to lease the minerals to himself. See, e.g., Manges v. Guerra, 673 S.W.2d 180 (Tex.
1984).
I (VB) interest in and to said rights and a lessor to the extent of the remaining one-
eighth (lis) interest therein.
'" W. VA. ConE § 22-8-2(5) (1985).
lIB W. VA. CODE § 22-4A-7(b}(1) (l985) deals with written consent. For a contrary view, see

LA. REV. STAT. ANN. § 30.9(c} (West Supp. 1985); Nunez v. Wainoco Oil & Gas, 488 So.2d 955
(La. 1986); McDaniel v. Moyer, .662 P.2d 309 (Okla. 1983).
113 Another detrimental side effect of this practice is to discourage mineral owners from leas- '" W. VA. ConE § 22-8-7(b)(5) (1985).
ing their interests. This will undoubtedly further hamper development of the oil and gas 121 CAL. PUB. REs. CODE § 3608 (West 1984) provides in part:
resource. Where land aggregating less than one acre is surrounded by other lands, which other
lands are subject to an oil and gas lease aggregating one acre or more, and if, under
282 JOURNAL OF ENERGY LAW AND POLICY [Vol. 7 1986] POOLING AND UNITIZATION 283

cation to unleased tracts of less than one acre,'" it provides the un- senting mineral owner was entitled to a basic royalty of '/8 th, the
leased owner solely with royalty benefits. Thus, the cash bonus paid Board of Oil, Gas and Mining and the Utah Supreme Court modified
to other mineral owners in the area will not be paid to the small tract the provision in resolving a dispute between an unleased owner and
mineral owner. This will encourage lessees to leave small tracts un- an operator in Bennion v_ Utah State Board of Oil, Gas & Mining."·
leased since no delay rentals or bonuses will have to be paid. Further, This case involved a classic problem with spacing units, pooling or-
these interests cannot share in the working interest by paying over ders, the rule of capture and the rights of non-consenting owners.
their proportionate share of well costs because, upon the spacing unit Bennion owned a small fractional unleased mineral interest in an
declaration, their lands are de jure treated as leased to the lessee of area which, by a Board order, had been pooled into 640-acre spacing
the surrounding acreage. An unleased owner, in attacking the validity units. In June 1973, Shell proposed a voluntary pooling order for the
of such a spacing order with its compulsory leasing ramifications, was section in question, and all owners except Bennion agreed. Shell com-
rebuffed in Hunter v. Justice's Court'23 on the grounds that the pro- pleted a well on the section but off of the acreage owned by Benn-
vision of a royalty interest adequately protected the unleased owner ion.''' The statute then in force provided that nonconsenting owners
from a taking of his property. The court noted that while other states were entitled to a V8 th royalty, but Shell took the position that, in
may also allow the unleased owner to participate in the working in- the absence of a pooling agreement or order, they owed nothing to
terest as well, that issue was a matter of legislative judgment, not Bennion. Bennion then filed a petition with the Board to force pool
constitutional imperative.'" the interest in question, but the order was not entered until 1979."·
At one time Utah also had apparently opted for the 'Is th solution Notwithstanding the statute's sole reference to a royalty interest for
in its pooling statute.'" Although the Act specified that the non-con- nonconsenting unleased owners, the Board trifurcated its order re-
garding payment by Shell to Bennion. For the period prior to payout
the provisions of Section 3600 to 3607. inclusive, of t'he Public Resources Code, the and beginning with first production, an unleased owner is entitled to
drilling or producing of a well on said land is declared to be a public nuisance, said a cost-free royalty. From the time of payout to the effective date of
land shall, for oil and gas development purposes and to prevent waste and to protect
the oil and gas rights of landowners, be deemed included in said oil and gas lease on
pooling, the non-consenting unleased owner is entitled to his share of
said other lands, and shall be subject to all the terms and provisions thereof. the revenue set off by his share of expenses, including those expenses
1 22 Id.
incurred prior to payout, Le., drilling costs. After the pooling order is
123 Hunter v. Justice's Court, 36 Cal. 2d, 315, 223 P.2d 465 (1950).

124 [d. at 468-69. The California statute does not expressly deal with unleased mineral owners
entered, the unleased owner is entitled to receive his proportionate
of tracts larger than 1 acre, except that it does provide that the state can force pool larger
parcels under a plan or agreement subject to such rules and regulations as the state may adopt.
CAL. PUB. REs. CODE § 3609 (West 1984). such nonconsenting owner's interest plus a reasonable charge for supervision and
". UTAH COOE ANN. § 40-6-6(g) (1966), amemied by UTAH CODE ANN. § 40-6-6 (Supp. 19S5). storage. [5] Each consenting and nonconsenting owner shall be entitled to receive,
The statute provides: subject to his paying or making arrangements with the owner or owners operating the
[11 Each pooling order shall make provision for the drilling and operation of a well well for the payment of all applicable royalties, over-riding royalties or other burdens
on the drilling unit, and for the payment of the reasonable actual cost thereof, includ~ on production and his respective share of current operating or other costs incidental
ing a reasonable charge for supervision and storage facilities. [2] As to each owner to the efficient operation of the well, his share, respectively, of production allocated to
who refuses to agree upon the terms for drilling and operating the well, the order the tract or tracts in which he holds an interest; provided, however, that a noncon-
shall provide for reimbursement for his share of the costs out of, and only out of, senting owner of a tract in a drilling unit, which is not subject to any lease or other

l
production from the unit representing his interest, excluding royalty or other interest contract for the development thereof for oil and gas shall be deemed to have a basic
not obligated to pay the cost thereof. [3J In the event of any dispute as to such costs, landowner's royalty of one-eighth (lh) or twelve and one-half percent (12- 1/2 %) of the
the commission shall determine the proper costs. [4J The order shall determine the \ production allocated to such tract.
12.8 Bennion v. Utah State Board of Oil, Gas & Mining, 675 P.2d 1135 (Utah 1983).
interest of each owner in the unit, and may provide in substance that as to each
l2.7 Id. at 1137. At this point, under the rule of capture, Bennion is without recourse. Since he
owner who agrees with the person or persons drilling and operating the well for the
payment by the owner of his share of the costs, such owner, unless he has agreed has not signed the pooling agreement, he would not be entitled to any share of.production from
otherwise, shall be entitled to receive, subject to royalty or similar obligations, th,e a well not located on the 80 acres in which he owned the fractional share. Havmg been created,
share of the production of the well applicable to the tract of the consenting owner, the spacing unit only provides for a limitation on drilling, not a pooling of interests. For the
and as to each owner who does not agree, he shall be entitled to receive from the difference between spacing and pooled units, see 5 E. KUNTZ, OIL AND GAS § 77.3 (1978).
person or persons drilling and operating the well on the unit his share of the produc· l2.8 Bennion, 675 P .2d at 1138. In the meantime the well had achieved payout, meaning that

tion applicable to his interest, after the person 01' persons drilling and operating the the value of the hydrocarbons recovered, had exceeded the cost of drilling and operating the
said well have recovered the share of the cost of drilling and operating applicable to well. In other words it was producing a profit for the working interest owners. Id.
284 JOURNAL OF ENERGY LAW AND POLICY [Vo!. 7 1986] POOLING AND UNITIZATION 285

share of the hydrocarbons in kind, if he pays his proportionate shar As amended, the Utah compulsory pooling provision codifies the
of the operating expenses of the well.I2. e Bennion decision.'3. It more clearly states that the royalty provision
This .approach is certainly not required by the statute, which onl is only payable until payout, plus risk penalty, but it does not state
speaks m terms of a royalty interest. Further, it is certainly differe~ that the unleased owner's interest thereafter turns into a working in-
from the approa~h taken by the ~lawson court, which maintained terest. The new provision also liberalizes the royalty amount by tying
that th~ royalty mterest was. reqUired to be maintained as long as the royalty to the average of the royalty received in the leases on the
~roductIOn. occurred because It was an inherent part of the mineral spacing unit rather than pegging the royalty at ",. th of production.
mterest bemg affected by the state's spacing and pooling laws."· The The Utah approach tends to penalize the unleased owner, by elimi-
court gives a rather crabbed reading to the statute when it conclude nating his right to both a royalty and working interest after payout.
that the royalty interest which the provision clearly creates someho: Given the fact that Utah has a risk penalty provision to compensate
gets merged into the working interest after payout.I'I Why should th the operator for the risk of a dry hole, it seems somewhat disingenu-
recoupment of drilling costs suddenly transform this royalty interes~ ous to suggest that the royalty interest suddenly merges into the
in!o ~ workin~ interest? The majority of states which statutorily treat working interest only after payout including risk penalty. The royalty
thiS Issue ObvIOusly consider the royalty interest as surviving payout interest should be continued throughout production and the working
cont!nuing through the life of the well.''' The court's discussion of interest share remaining after deducting the specified royalty should
the Issue of the termination of the royalty interest also confuses the be subject to the normal rules for non-consenting working interest
statute's provision relating to the sharing of costs of working interest owners. Where the statute allows a risk penalty, the unleased owner
owners and mineral owners. 13 ' The court erroneously suggests that is not getting a windfall, as was the case in Slawson, since the pen-
the c~st. of drilling should b~. deducted from each non-consenting alty provision will act as an incentive to lease the interest prior to
?wner s mterest, but the provISIon they quote refers only to working pooling or spacing in order to receive a bonus as part of that transac-
mterest owners who have no royalty interest. 1" tion. If the penalty reflects the risk of drilling, it will provide incen-
tives for the unleased owner to participate in drilling the well.
129 Id. at 1138.39. D. Option State
130 See supra text accompanying notes 107 and 112.
131 Bennion, 675 P.2d at 1142.
Washington, a state with little production, has the most extensive
13:1. See supra text accompanying notes 93.119. statutory treatment for unleased mineral owners. I3 • It is probably the
133 Bennion, 675 P.2d at 1142. The court states: best alternative because it attempts to mirror the marketplace and
C. The Cost"Free Royalty provide a balance between the interests of the unleased owner and
!he Board's calculation of Bennion's one·eighth royalty interest for the period
prior to payout made no deduction for expenses. However, in the Board's view once I,
the operator. The statute creates three different options for the un-
payout occurred the royalty interest "merged" with the working interest. Thereafter leased owner once a pooling order has been entered covering the un-
~ennion's share was calculate~ on· the basis of his fractional share of the workin~ leased lands!" The first option is the modified Va -",. election,
mterest (2.94898 percent), subject to his payment of his fractional share of the drill-
ing and operating expenses from the beginning of development and drilling. Bennion
charges that this calculation deprived him of his statutory "basic landowners' roy- 13~The statute now provides:
alty," ,:",hich he contends should be cost-free as to all costs incurred during the period (7) The order shall provide that:
for whICh the royalty was paid (i.e., prior to payout). (b) A nonconsenting owner of a tract in a drilling unit~ which is not subject to a lease
Here also, the Board made a reasonable-indeed, the only permissi- or other contract for the development of oil and gas, shall receive as a royalty the
ble-con?truction of its governing statut~. The fourth sentence of subse'ction (g) average landowners royalty attributable to each tract within the drilling unit, deter-
(quo~ed In note 2, supra), which prescribes the nonconsenting owner's share of pro- mined prior to the commencement of drilling and payable from the production allo-
duction after payout, makes the owner's rights subject to the operator's first recover- cated to each tract until the consenting owners have recovered the costs as provided
ing the "share of the cost of drilling and operating applicable to such nonconsenting in subsection (6).
?wner's int?rest." (Emphasis added.) Since the cost of drilling is, by definition, a cost UTAH CODE ANN. § 46-6-6(7) (Supp. 1985).
Incurred prIOr to payout, Bennion's argument that he is entitled to a cost-free royalty ". WASH. REV. CODE ANN. § 78.52.250(4) (Supp. 19S6).
prior to payout is meritless. In The statute provides:
[d. (4) A nonconsenting owner of a tract in a development unit which is not subject to
134 Id. any lease or other contract for the development thereof for oil and gas shall elect
1986] POOLING AND UNITIZATION 28.7
U.I<' ENERGY LAW AND POLICY [Vol. .7

T
zoo dUUltNAL

whereby the unleased owner is entitled to a royalty of V.th or a treated as opting for the modified % - Va alternative.
higher royalty if that is the basic royalty received by other pooled
lands. The owner of the remaining interest is treated as a working E. The Unclassified Residuary
I.
interest owner and is given the right to participate or be carried with Each of the several other states which deal with the unleased
a risk penalty on certain types of costs."· The statute, however, mod- owner take a unique approach to the problem. Virginia, for example,
ifies the unleased owner's right to a higher royalty by limiting that allows the unleased owner to escape the risk penalty authorized to be
owner's right to receive this "presumed" royalty to the period prior imposed on other working interest owners who choose to be car-
to payout. After payout, the landowner only receives the basic royalty ried.H2 The statute also obliquely authorizes an unleased owner to
until production ceases. participate in the operation under such terms and conditions as he
The second option authorizes the unleased owner to grant a lease and the operator agree to. H3 It does not provide for the options avail-
to the operator at the current market price for comparable leases or able to the non-consenting unleased owner in the event that a volun-
interests."· In addition, the statute lists certain provisions in leases tary agreement cannot be worked out.'" .,
or pooling orders as they relate to non-consenting unleased owners Louisiana, which recently amended its compulsor~ poolIng proVI-
which, if included, make the order or lease unfair and therefore inva- sions to deal with the issue of unleased owners and rIsk penalty, has
lid. H• The last option allows the unleased owner to treat his entire chosen to treat the unleased owner solely as a working interest
interest as a working interest and pay his pro rata share of the costs
of the well and receive his pro rata share of production.'" If the un-
... VA. ConE § 45.1-302(C)(2) (Supp. 1985).
leased owner fails to make an election within the fifteen day period H3 [d. § 45.1-302(B). The statute provides in part: .
allowed after the entry of the pooling order, he is automatically The owner of an unleased tract who elects to be a participating operator shall m
addition to his share of production, be entitled to participate in accordance with the
terms and conditions which he and the operator agree upon.
within fifteen days of the issuance of the pooling order or such further time as the Id.
committee shall, in the order, allow: ... Id. § 45.1-302(C). .
(a) To be treated as a nonconsenting owner as provided in subsections (2) and (3) of The statute is also somewhat confusing in the way it defines a well operator, a royalty owner
this section and is deemed to have a basic landowner's royalty of one-eighth, or and a participating operator. One cannot easily determine from the statute whether or not the
twelve and one-half percent, of the production allocated to the tract, unless as a unleased owner is entitled to both royalty owner and well operator status for purposes of the
higher basic royalty has been established in the development unit. If a higher royalty compulsory pooling provisions. The statute provides in part:
has been established, then the nonconsenting owner of a nonleased tract shall receive 40. "Owner" means (i) when used with reference to any well, any person who o~~,
the higher basic royalty. This presumed royalty shall exist only during the time that operates, or has the right to operate such a well as principal or as lessee, and (11)
costs and expenses are being recovered under subsection (2) of this section. and is when used with reference to any coal seam, any person who owns, leases, operates, or
intended to assure that the owner of a nonleased tract receive 'a basic royalty free of has the right to operate the coal seam;
all costs at all times. Notwithstanding anything herein to the contrary, the owner 41. "Participating operator" or "participating well ope!"a.tor" means ~ well o~er~tor
shall at all times retain his or her entire ownership of the property, including the who elects to bear a share of the risks and costs of drillIng, completmg, eqUIppmg,
right to execute an oil and gas lease on any termS negotiated, and be entitled to all operating, plugging and abandoning a well on a drilling unit and to rec~ive a sh~~ of
production subject to subsection (2) of this section; or production from the well equal to the proportion which the acreage I.n.the d:lllmg
(b) To grant a lease to the operator at the current fair market value for that interest unit he owns or holds under lease bears to the total acreage of the drilling umt;
for comparable leases or interests at the time of the commencement of drilling; or 52. "Royalty owner" means any owner of oil and gas in place, or oil and gas rights, to
(c) To pay his or he,r pro rata share of the costs of the well or wells in the develop- the extent that such owner is not a well operator- or a gas operator.
ment unit and receive his or her pro rata share of production, if any. 65. "Well operator" means any person who has the right to operate or does operate a
A nonconsenting owner who does not make an election as provided in this subsection well. For purposes of oil and gas conservation under Article 2 (§ 45.1-299 et se.q.) of
is deemed to have elected to be treated under (a) of this subsection. this chapter, the term means any owner of the right to develop and produc~ 011 and
WASH. REV. ConE ANN. § 7S.52.250(4) (Supp. 1986) gas from a pool and to appropriate the oil and gas produced. therefro~ elt~er for
j
u, WASH. REV. COOE ANN. § 78.52.240(2-3) (Supp. 1986). himself or for himself and others. In the event there is no oil or gas lease In eXistence
'" Id. § 78.52.250(4)(b). with respect to the tract in question, the owner of the oil and gas rights therein s~aU
140 [d. § 78.52.253. The provisions relate to preferential rights of the operator to purchase
be considered a well operator of the oil and gas in that portion of the pool underlymg
mineral interests in the unit, calls or options to purchase production from the unit, imposition the tract which he owns. In the event that the. oil is owned separately from the g:as'
of unreasonable operating charges or prohibition against nonoperators questioning the 9pera- the definitions contained herein shall apply separately to the owners of the respective
tion of the unit. interests.
,.. Id. § 78.52.250(4)(c). VA. CODE § 45.1-288 (40, 41. 52 and 65) (Supp. 1985).
288 JOURNAL OF ENERGY LAW AND POLICY [Vol. 7 1986] POOLING AND UNITIZATION 289

owner.'" As such, the owner has the election to participate or be car- permanent or temporary; a buy-in option; and an overriding royalty
ried, but, unlike the working interest owner who is subject to a risk buy-out option. A catch-all provision should be included that allows
penalty for nonparticipation, the statute specifically exempts the un- the state agency more discretion to fashion innovative orders to deal
leased owner from any risk charge.'" Therefore, the unleased owner with problems such as requests for partial participation. It is also im-
can sit back and be carried without risk and will never have to par- portant that the statute allow a range of risk penalty figures to be set
ticipate in the drilling costs. While that would seem to overcompen_ by the Commission depending on its determination of the amount of
sate the unleased owner, the statute does not provide for a royalty risk that accompanies the drilling of the pooled or unitized well. The
payment; and if the well never achieves a payout status, the unleased statute may also provide a laundry list of rel~vant factors as long as
owner will have received nothing even though his mineral estate they are not treated as exclusive considerations. The statute should
would have been essentially extinguished. require the election to b~ made within a limited time with a forced
election should the non-consenting owner fail to respond. Reference
IV. CONCLUSION to voluntary pooling or unitization agreements dealing with the same
or similar geological conditions should be made when available.
Compulsory pooling and unitization is a vital regulatory tool cre- Those will reflect th~ private sector's assessment of the actual risks
ated to conserve oil and gas, protect correlative rights and prevent involved in the drilling program. A statute encompassing these major
waste. The aim of the state statutory and regulatory program should features would come closer to attaining the objectives ofa compul-
be to achieve those objectives in an economically efficient manner. sory pooling and unitization regulatory program.
The two major impediments to preventing the attainment of these The greatest need in ·the area of how to deal with unleased mineral
goals are the "carried" interest problem referred to in my introduc- owners is to expressly include them within the statutory scheme.
tory statement and the silent treatment given to unleased owners. Again the best way to deal with this problem is to provide the un-
Compulsory pooling and unitization statutes which give the non- leased owner several options. The Washington pooling and unitiza-
consenting working interest owner a free ride, discourage the use of tion statute'·' is an excellent paradigm. The options would include
the regulatory scheme,"7 Working interest owners do not want to treating the unleased owner as both a working and royalty interest
bear the entire risk of a dry or marginally productive well when they owner with the amount of royalty dependent on the average royalty
must share their profits with the non-consenting owners. The pre- in the field. The working interest share would then fall within the
ferred alternative, which would probably encourage more private options granted to other nonconsenting working interest owners in
agreements, is to have a statute which authorizes the administrative the pooled or unitized field. The second option would authorize the
agency to afford the non-consenting working interest owner several leasing of the unleased owner's interest at the current market price
alternative choices. The statute should give both direction and dis- for comparable leases. The final option would allow the entire UIl-
cretion to the administrative agency to implement the option pro- leased interest to be treated as a working interest and allow the
gram."" A listing of alternatives should include: a risk penalty provi- owner to be carried with a penalty or pay his pro rata share of ex-
sion for those who wish to be carried; a transfer option, either penses. Again, the order should provid~ for a mandatory choice if the
owner does not make a voluntary election after a short period of
... LA. REv. STAT. ANN. § 30:10(2) (West Supp. 1985). time.
146 ld. § 30:1O(e). The statute provides in part: Compulsory pooling and unitization statutes provide a mechanism
(e) The provisions of Paragraph 2(b) above with respect to the risk charge shall not to prevent waste, conserve resources and protect correlative rights.
apply to any unleased interest not subject to an oil. gas, and mineral lease. Notwith-
standing the provisions of Paragraph 2(b) the royaItyowner and overriding royalty
As presently written, several state statutory schemes not only do not
owner shall receive that portion of production due to them under the terms of the achieve those goals, but in fact hinder achievement through the pri-
contract creating the royalty. vate market sector. Movement away from treating working interests
[d.
,,, See, e.g., ARK. STAT. ANN. § 53-115 (A-1)(c) (1971);
ILL. ANN. STAT. ch. 96V" § 5436(d)
as free rides, along with an explicit policy towards unleased owners,
(Smith-Hurd 1979), S.D. CODIFlED LAWS ANN. § 45-9-31 (1983).
146 For example the South Dakota statute which merely provides for just and reasonable
alternatives is too broad. See S.D, CODIFIED LAWS ANN. § 45~9-31 (1983). ,.. WASH. REV. CODE ANN. § 78.52.250(4) (Supp. 1986).
290 JOURNAL OF ENERGY LAW AND POLICY [Vol. 7

will go a long way to maximizing the efficiency of a compulsory pool-


ing and unitization scheme.

You might also like